write a research paper on the issue of social economic effects on good governance with respect to the economic growth of nation. select a case study of a nation in the third world countries and write

105









MATTHEW NIYONGABO




Social economic effect of good governance on the economic growth of nations: Case study of Kenya








A Project Proposal in Partial Fulfillment for the Award of Doctorate in Leadership Administration and Management at North Western Christian University

DECLARATION

I declare that this research project is my original work and has never been submitted to any other university for the award of a degree.


Signature…………………………. Date……………………………





Declaration by the Supervisor

I declare that this research project has been submitted for examination with my approval as the University supervisor.


Signature…………………………. Date……………………………

Eldoret, KENYA


Acknowledgement

I do appreciate the moral, spiritual and financial support that was accorded to me towards this project by both my family members and Zion Holy City Pentecostal Church. I also give thanks to Northwestern Christian university Eldoret campus Director, Apostle Hannah Wairimu and my classmates for their spiritual, moral and technical support given to me towards this process. I also wish to address my thanks to the government of Kenya for the immense liberty and permission. Finally, I do appreciate the technical support and guidance given to me to accomplish this process by Mr. Emmanuel.
















Dedication

I do dedicate this project to my beloved parents Edmond Nyabenda and Yollanda Bankuwiha. Jenifer Nininahazwe for her moral and financial support, Professor Miongechong for the spiritual support, Teresiah wangari, Dr.Robinson Makoha. More also to the almighty God for the gift of life, calling and strength that he has blessed me with to accomplish this project.





Vocabularies/Acronyms

GDP- Gross Domestic Product

KANU Kenya African National Union

NEPAD The New Partnership for Africa’s Development

WB World Bank

MENA Middle East and North Africa

Kenyatta First President of Kenya

Moi Second president of Kenya

Kibaki Third president of Kenya















Table of Contents

Contents

DECLARATION 1

Acknowledgement 2

Vocabularies/Acronyms 4

Contents 5

Abstract 7

CHAPTER 1 8

1.1Introduction 8

1.2 Background of the Study 8

1.3 Statement of the Problem 11

1.4 Study Significance 13

1.5 Research Methodology 14

1.6 Purpose of the Study 14

1.7 Theoretical Framework 14

1.8 Research Objectives 15

1.9 Research Questions 15

1.9.1 Research Assumptions 15

1.9.2 Scope of the Study 16

1.10 Justification of the Study 17

Chapter 2 17

2.1 Introduction 17

2.2 Quality of Governance 26

2.3 Relationship between Good Governance and Economic Growth 32

2.4 Good Governance Explained 38

2.5 Service Delivery Theories 47

2.5.1 The Shared Governance Theory 47

2.6 Conflict Theory 52

2.7 Feedback Mechanisms Theories 54

2.7.1 The Citizen Involvement Theory 54

2.9 Citizen Empowerment 60

2.10 Governance and major growth theories 68

CHAPTER 3: RESEARCH METHODOLOGY 79

3.0 Introduction 79

3.1 Research Design 79

3.2 Population and Sampling 80

3.3 Data Collection 81

3.4 Data Analysis 84

3.5 Research Quality 85

3.6 Ethical Considerations 86

Chapter 4: DATA ANALYSIS, INTERPRETATION, AND PRESENTATION 89

4.0 Introduction 89

4.1 Questionnaire Response 89

4.2 Questionnaire Response Rate 89

4.3 Study Demography 90

4.4 Educational Level 90

4.5 Positive Indication of governance 91

4.6 Benefits of Proper Governance 92

CHAPTER 5: SUMMARY, CONCLUSION AND RECOMMENDATIONS 94

5.0 Introduction 94

Conclusion 96

Recommendations 96

References 99

Abstract

Sub-Sahara African countries have had a checkered past when it comes to good governance and institutions. Increasingly, economists and policy makers are recognizing the importance of governance and institutions for economic growth and development. The New Partnership for Africa's Development (NEPAD) has four main goals: eradicating poverty, promoting sustainable growth and development, integrating Africa into the world's economy, and accelerating the empowerment of women. Using fixed and random effects, and Arellano-Bond models, this paper investigates the role of governance in explaining the sub-optimal economic growth performance of African economies. Our results suggest that good governance or lack thereof, contributes to the differences in growth of African countries. Furthermore, our results indicate that the role of governance on economic growth depends on the level of income. In a nutshell, our results demonstrate that without the establishment and maintenance of good governance, achieving the goals of NEPAD will be hampered in Africa.

CHAPTER 1
    1. Introduction

Kenya is a land endowed with much resources that can sustain its development and feed its people. Leadership Is a critical tool that determines the level of achievement a nation, institution, or organization can attain. In the recent times, Kenya, like most African nations has began experiencing good leadership that has registered increased development and a high appetite for foreign development and investment. The paper brings issues around governance with Kenya as the case study in examining the social economic effect of good governance through literature review of the past cases and a case study that looks into the specific factors under study.

1.2 Background of the Study

It is every nation’s dream to grow and compete favorably with the rest of nations in an increasingly global world. In order to achieve this desire, the political leadership and government policies on development have to align and give room for players in the diverse industry to work independently in a cool political atmosphere. In Kenya, the pace of development has picked up with the reason being attributed to the development in governance standards that has elicited the present success. Development is directly tied to the governance patterns fixed on key leaders that hold the economy close to their heart. Improper leadership and governance always result in lower returns, cases of corruption, and an economy that fails to pick-up. The aspect of governance is an all-round affair that encompasses the political, economic, social, and cultural factor all of which contribute to an efficient growth in the GDP. The past two decades in Kenya have exhibited a spirited growth in the economy attributed to the kind of leadership in all the four dimensions.

International trade policy consists of bilateral and multilateral arrangements between countries I and dictates the terms of commerce between them. These trade policies and relations vary in ! scope and content but generally depend on the structure of the economy of a particular country. In developing countries, trade policy-making is shaped by the interaction of international and domestic factors - economic and political. At the international level, the processes of globalization play a major role in influencing and shaping subsequent trade policies. At the domestic level, policy-making is intimately linked with the nature of the public-private relationship as well as the autonomy of state agencies and their institutional strength and capacity. Trade policies and their coherency clearly have a bearing on the overall trade strategy pursued and consequently on the economic gains from trade. Kenya's trade policy development has evolved through the following distinct policy orientations: import Substitution Policies (1960s -80s); Trade Liberalization through Structural Adjustment Policies (SAPs) (1980s) and Export Oriented Policies (1990s). Presently Kenya's Trade regime is guided by market-driven principles of liberalization under the World Trade Organization (WTO) and the increased efforts in the regional economic integration that has resulted in the establishment of the East African Community (EAC), Common Market for Eastern and Southern Africa (COMESA.) This study reflects on Kenya's international trade experiences and examines the institutional arrangements and interaction of its actors in the trade policy formulation and negotiations processes. It also identifies and contributes to a better understanding of the factors that constrain effective formulation, negotiation, monitoring and evaluation of the country's international trade policy.

Therefore, the fate of the nation hanged on the leadership and the ability of the nation’s governance to strike trade deals through creating a good business environment that attracts investors.

The periods of 70s to 90s period were characterized by less development given the one-party issues that prevented the political wing from growing and rendering its benefits to the nation. Cases of dictatorship and open reward of the political class based on their affiliation prevented the free will and potential of the nation to grow as those that opposed the awarding were restrained and taken into political oblivion. However, the coming of multi-party in 1992 tagged along renewed hope for the nation with a raft of changes on the way. A decade later, after the exit of the long-serving regime KANU, a sigh of relief engulfed the nation. The period recorded a renewed growth in the infrastructure, manufacturing, and processing sectors that were steered by proper governance. The facts underlined inform the benefits of proper governance and its reflection on the development of a nation’s economy.

1.3 Statement of the Problem

Governance is and remains to be a determining factor in as far as a country, continent, or world can go in achieving its socio-economic growth. The type of leadership a place has is directly related to the growth of a given place or region. Poor governance has always been a recipe of chaos and confusion that leads to lower or reduced development.

Governance in Kenya has faced many challenges leading to cases of poor economic performance over the past decades. It is commonly acknowledged that governance steers development, where the reverse leads to underdevelopment. The promulgation of the new constitution brought to an end a clamor that had persisted for more than twenty years that marked a period of agitation for better governance and greater democratic space. The structure of government was changed radically in the new constitution so as to position devolution at the core of national life.

Chapter eleven of the constitution of Kenya provide for devolution, its objects and principles, the county governments, functions and powers of the national and county governments and relationships between levels of governments.

To achieve these objectives, the constitution established 47 county governments in addition to the national government. Each county will have a government consisting of County assembly and County Executive. Since independence, Kenya has had long history o f bad governance, from the oppression of the British Colonial government, to the Kenyatta and Moi dictatorship and previously the Kibaki ineffective, undisciplined and un-responsive administration. Kenya has had a centralized form of government characterized by Constitutional limitations, failure to implement national policies, lethargy in the civil service, corruption, tribalism and impunity.

At the heart of the clamor for a new constitution was a determination by the people of Kenya to devolve governance and decision making so as to give them a greater say in how they and their resources are governed. Therefore, Kenyans have had high hopes for devolution so that they could change the kind of governance to have a government characterized by accountability, effectiveness, efficiency and responsiveness. Although efforts have been made to devolve governance in the past, the central government has always played an active role in undermining the same efforts hence the long history of unequal distribution of resources, poverty, exclusion of minorities, marginalization of some regions and communities of the country and thereby skewed development.

These mistakes can only be, to some extent, rectified through the proper establishment and operationalization of devolved governance so that the locals can manage and account for their own resources. Therefore, the paper seeks to point out the effects of proper governance on development of a nation using the case of Kenya as documented in its development record in the past two decades. The research shall outline the problem of poor governance in bringing up a struggling economy.

1.4 Study Significance

Governance determines a lot in the process of growth and development and thus remains a critical factor in understanding the rising and falling of economies. Enforcement of good governance leads to positive outcomes that steer a nation’s growth. The study findings and recommendations shall be important in understanding the core factors that lead to a given situation. The study shall be significant to the students in the leadership and administration in bettering their skills in operating different entities of the economy. Moreover, the research findings shall be important to policy developers and leaders in the governance sector in bettering their skills towards posterity. The study recommendations shall be important to the policy developers, future researchers, the prosecution departments, anti-corruption entities, and general public in understanding the underlying factors to proper governance.

1.5 Research Methodology

The research uses several means towards achieving its end goals in understanding and overcoming corruption. The research involved evaluation of the existing literature on the identified research topic through the use of secondary data obtained from reliable sources including books, journals, government reports, documentaries, e-books, study reports, and past research works on corruption. Further, the research shall employ the use of questionnaires and interview in finding out the extent to which the issue prevails in the government departments. The combination of the two shall be essential in finding out and accomplishing the objectives to the research topic.

1.6 Purpose of the Study

The study seeks to establish aspects surrounding good governance and their benefits to an all-round economic growth. It purposes to research on governance, its implications and examples of benefits accrued from proper leadership. The study shall help in understanding the determining factors to good governance as well as their benefits to the subjects as evidenced in the case of Kenya and its development in the last two decades.

1.7 Theoretical Framework

The research shall utilize the Utilitarianism theory in explaining the effects of good governance on the socio-economic development. Utilitarianism theory was developed by Jeremy Bentham and John Stuart Mill. The theory is based on morality which advocates for acts that promote the overall goodness or happiness of individual while rejecting actions that cause unpleasant feeling or harm upon people. In this respect, it advocates for economic, social, and political good for the same of the people in bettering a society. The theory shall remain important towards discovering the good and pointing out the benefits it renders to the society.

1.8 Research Objectives

The objectives of this research are divided into two comprising the main objective and specific objectives. The main objective of this research study is to assess the impact governance on the development of a nation.

However, the specific objectives include:

  • To examine the aspect of governance in Kenya

  • To identify the benefits it renders to diverse entities

  • To examine the gaps obtained in improper governance situations

  • To suggest appropriate strategies to proper governance

1.9 Research Questions

- What is governance and how is it achieved?

-what aspects of governance are key to development?

-what are the benefits of good governance to a nation?

-what are the gaps in exercising proper governance?

1.9.1 Research Assumptions

This research study was based on the assumption that; proper governance leads to development in the diverse sectors of the economy. Compliance to governance standards and remaining true to its values leads to development among partners in the economic sectors. The assumptions were based on the differences experienced in the previous regimes as opposed to the present operating in the last two decades in Kenya. .

1.9.2 Scope of the Study

The research acknowledges the steps taken in the process of enhancing governance. The study uses the case of devolved government and the national government to demonstrate the values of proper governance to the development exhibited across the nation. The research targets persons in the national and the county government leadership in obtaining information on the issue governance. In so doing, the study shall target government offices at both levels in ascertaining the measures embraced in developing governance to its people. The scope of study shall be limited to Uasin Gishu County, examining the leadership and devolution case and its effects on socio-economic development.

write a research paper on the issue of social economic effects on good governance with respect to the economic growth of  nation. select a case study of a nation in the third world countries and write 1

1.10 Justification of the Study

The global world focuses on good governance in realizing benefits for its nation. The differences in the government abilities around the world relates to opportunities and proper governance in implementing a change process. Thus, the study is important in portraying the effect of governance on the development aiming on the positive utilization of power to turn opportunities into benefits for the people. The study findings shall propel the need for good governance in ripping the benefits for the people. The study is justified in explaining the increased developments experienced in Kenya since the change of power in the last two decades of change.

Chapter 2 2.1 Introduction

Since the end of the Cold War until the early 1990’s, however, the issue of good governance has become an important concept in the international development debates and policy discourse. The working definition of what constitutes good governance has evolved over the years. Schneider (1999) defines good governance as the exercise of authority, or control to manage a country’s affairs and resources. The United States Agency for International Development (USAID, 2002), on the other hand, defines good governance as a complex system of interaction among structures, traditions, functions, and processes characterized by values of accountability, transparency, and participation. The UNDP (2002) defines good governance as striving for rule of law, transparency, equity, effectiveness /efficiency, accountability, and strategic vision in the exercise of political, economic, and administrative authority. Historically, sub-Saharan African countries have had a checkered good governance record in comparison to other regions of the world. These countries have been bogged down with political instability, government ineffectiveness, the lack of rule of law, and serious problems of corruption which are signs of bad governance. With respect to the importance of good governance to development, improving governance in this region has been given a central place in the New Partnership for Africa’s Development (NEPAD). Over the past few years, some countries in this region including, but not limited to Botswana and Ghana, have made significant progress in terms of governance.

The global distribution of income shows a highly uneven pattern of distribution. For instance, in 2015, the per capita GDP of North America was at least 34 times higher than the per capita GDP in South Asia and Sub-Saharan Africa (Atkinson, A. B., & Bourguignon, F. (Eds.). (2014). ). In addition to that, countries in some parts of the world have grown strongly, over time, while countries in other regions have not. The average nominal GDP in East Asia and the Pacific countries in 2015 increased by 3711 times in comparison with the figures in 1968. But in the same period, the countries in Sub-Saharan Africa grew only 868 times (The World Bank, 2016). These figures reveal a growth difference in the different parts of the world. Although the theoretical models including the Solow model and new growth theory provide some level of explanation for the economic growth within a particular geographic boundary, understanding of economic growth is still incomplete (Atkinson, A. B., & Bourguignon, F. (Eds.). (2014).

In addition to that, the existing growth models fail to provide a complete explanation for the cross-country growth differences. Human capital accumulation, physical capital accumulation, and technological progress are important determinants of economic growth in the major growth models. The concept of governance and its importance to economic growth was raised in the early 1990s (Atkinson & Bourguignon, 2014). Governance is a broad concept with great complexity to its major pillars. Governance is defined as a set of traditions and institutions that can be used to exercise the power of authority. Six basic dimensions of the governance are included political stability and absence of violence/terrorism, voice and accountability, government effectiveness, regulatory quality, control of corruption and the rule of law (Atkinson & Bourguignon, 2014). These governance characteristics may influence several critical institutions that are essential for economic growth. These key institutions include well-defined property rights, unbiased contract enforcement, reduced information gap and stable macroeconomic conditions. The governance indicators influence on these and eventually decide the country's economic growth in two ways.

2.1.1 Good Governance

Economists agree that governance is one of the critical factors explaining the divergence in performance across developing countries. The differences of view between economists regarding governance are to do first, with the types of state capacities that constitute the critical governance capacities necessary for the acceleration of development and secondly, with the importance of governance relative to other factors at early stages of development. On the first issue, there is an important empirical and theoretical controversy between liberal economists who constitute the mainstream consensus on good governance and statist and heterodox institutional economists who agree that governance is critical for economic development but argue that theory and evidence show that the governance capacities required for successful development are substantially different from those identified by the good governance analysis. The economists in favor of good governance argue that the critical state capacities are those that maintain efficient markets and restrict the activities of states to the provision of necessary public goods to minimize rent seeking and government failure. The relative failure of many developing country states are explained by the attempts of their states to do too much, resulting in the unleashing of unproductive rent-seeking activities and the crowding out of productive market ones. The empirical support for this argument typically comes from cross-sectional data on governance in developing countries that shows that in general, countries with better governance defined in these terms performed better. In contrast, heterodox institutional economists base their argument on case studies of rapid growth in the last fifty years. This evidence suggests that rapid growth was associated with governance capacities quite different from those identified in the good governance model. States that did best in terms of achieving convergence with advanced countries had the capacity to achieve and sustain high rates of investment and to implement policies that encouraged the acquisition and learning of new technologies rapidly. The institutions and strategies that achieved these varied from country to country, depending on their initial conditions and political constraints, but all successful states had governance capacities that could achieve these functions. This diversity in governance capacities in successful developers means that we cannot necessarily identify simple patterns in the governance capacities of successful states, but nevertheless, we can identify broad patterns in the functions that successful states performed, and this can provide useful insights for reform policy in the next tier of developers. The empirical and theoretical issues involved here clearly have critical policy implications for reform efforts in developing countries. The second area of disagreement concerns the relative importance of governance reforms in accelerating development in countries at low levels of development. An important challenge to the mainstream good governance approach to reform in Africa has come from Sachs and others (2004) who argue that at the levels of development seen in Africa and given the development constraints faced by that continent, a focus on governance reforms is misguided. They support their argument with an empirical analysis that shows that the differences in performance between African countries is not explained by differences in their quality of governance (measured according to the criteria of good governance) once differences in their levels of development have been accounted for. The important policy conclusion that they derive is that in Africa the emphasis has to be on a big push based on aid-supported investment in infrastructure and disease control.

Good governance has several characteristics. It is participatory, consensus oriented, accountable, transparent, responsive, effective, efficient, equitable, and inclusive and follows the rule of law. At a minimum, good governance requires fair legal frameworks that are enforced impartially by an independent judiciary and its decisions and enforcement are transparent or carried out in a manner that follows established rules and regulations. Since accountability cannot be enforced without transparency and the rule of law, accountability is a key requirement of good governance. Not only governmental institutions, but also private sector and civil society organizations must be accountable to the public and to their institutional stakeholders.

The United Nations Millennium Project, the United Nations Development Programme’s Human Development Reports, and the World Bank’s annual World Development Reports each list over one hundred “must do” items for countries to achieve good governance. Even allowing for the considerable overlap among the various items, it is a formidable agenda-not only for the world’s least developed and post-conflict countries, but also for many middle-income and transitional economies. However, the reports provide little prioritization or guidance regarding what governance items are essential and what can wait, how they should be sequenced and implemented, how much they will cost and how they will be paid for. They also suffer from flaws typical to commissioned reports: a tendency to provide “one-size-fits-all” prescriptions, despite the fact that research shows, although governance reforms share commonalities, they must also be judiciously determined on a country-by-country basis-the institutional innovations tailored to local political and institutional realities, with the most essential sequenced in first. The various report recommendations can be broadly divided into two sections: the general and the substantive. The general emphasize “capacity development,” which includes both the building of effective states (which can deliver public goods and services to the populace and ensure peace and stability), and an empowered and responsive society which can hold states accountable for their actions. The reports correctly note that poor or inadequate governance may not always be the result of venal or rapacious leadership, but because the state may suffer from weak formal political institutions and lack the resources and capacity to manage an efficient public administration. However, what is not always appreciated is that good governance cannot be had on the cheap simply through the implementation of bureaucratic and administrative policies.

Moreover, governance reforms without concomitant economic reforms are doomed to failure. Again, research shows that political-institutional reforms are more successful in settings where economic development already has started to take place. This is not to imply that political development is simply a consequence of economic development, but to underscore that institution building and consolidation are more likely to succeed where development already has taken place, or is taking place. Arguably, many of the items listed on the good governance agenda as preconditions for development are actually consequences of it. The implications are profound: institution building and the promotion of good governance demand simultaneous commitment to economic development. That is, what needs to be measured is the government’s delivery of public goods and not just its budgetary provisions, its actual accomplishments, and its good intentions. Substantively, the reports view institution building, democracy, and political-economic decentralization as essential for good governance and economic development. Although intuitively appealing, the questions of precisely how each contributes to democratic institutionalization and economic development are poorly understood-and the reports’ overly sanguine rhetorical statements shed little light on these issues. For example, how does a society devise an institutional framework that nurtures both democracy and market economies; how does it best ensure that government has sufficient power to provide security and public services, while being inhibited from predation on its own citizenry; how can democratic governance, economic growth, and human development become mutually reinforcing; or, how does a society prevent the devolution and decentralization of political-economic authority from exacerbating regional or particularistic divisions? Although the reports do not provide a nuanced discussion of these issues, a growing body of research sheds useful insights into these important issues. The following sections draw on this scholarly research to elaborate these concerns.

While informal interpersonal exchanges and social networks can serve the needs of traditional societies, modern economies (given their specialization and complex division of labor) require formalized political, judicial, and economic rules. In providing specific rules of the game, political and economic institutions create the conditions that enable the functioning of a modern economy. That is, formal institutions, by securing property rights, establishing a polity and judicial system, and implementing flexible laws that allow a range of organizational structures, create an economic environment that induces increasing productivity. To North, institutions are “growth enhancing” because they reduce uncertainty and transaction costs. Thus, North’s paradigm is often labeled as the “new institutionalism” because it has at its core a set of ideas derived from the analysis of “transaction costs”-that is, costs that result from the imperfect character of real-world institutions and that have to be surmounted in order for economic activity to occur. Specifically, the institutional framework affects growth because it is integral to the amount spent on both the costs of transactions and the costs of transformation inherent in the production process. Transaction costs are far higher when property rights of the rule of law are absent and not enforced. In such situations, private firms typically operate on a small scale and rely on extra-legal means to function. Conversely, an institutional environment that provides impartial third-party enforcement of agreements promotes exchange and trade because the parties know that a good or service will be delivered after it is paid for. Because institutions and the enforcement of rules largely determine the costs of transacting, good institutions can also minimize transaction costs-or costs incurred in making an economic exchange. Both political and economic institutions are necessary to sufficiently reduce transaction costs in order to make potential gains from trade realizable.

2.2 Quality of Governance

Governance quality is an important variable to explain investment rate which means one way to promote economic growth is improving the capital market and investment climate. Meanwhile, there are some other approaches by which good governance can improve economic performance, such as a stable bureaucratic system promoting long-term investment in the private sector (Moore, 2004). Bureaucratic professionalization encourages investment in public facilities; reduction of corruption and encouraging productive investment. Moreover, a good economic power structure promotes the optimization of resource allocation of a political power structure thus affecting economy system and economic policy.

Recently good governance has become conditionality for the disbursement of development assistance to less developed nations. Furthermore, foreign investors are increasingly basing their investment decisions on good governance. Granted, there are some economists including Owens (1987), and Sen (1990) who recognized and advocated for the need for political and economic freedom as an essential dimension for economic growth, these studies were theoretical discourses rather than being empirical expositions. Since 1990s, however, empirical studies in this area have dealt with the effects of lack of good governance rather than its direct impact on the economic growth of emerging countries. Given that the governance situation differs from one sub-Saharan African country to the other, the objectives of this inquiry are twofold. First, we investigate the effect of various governance indices on economic growth of sub-Saharan African countries while considering the conventional sources of growth. Second, we investigate whether the impact of these governance indicators differ by the conditional distribution of economic growth. Thus, we investigate whether the impact of governance on economic growth depends on the relative level of growth.

2.2.1 Growth Enhancing Governance

Growth Enhancing Governance

The prediction of the theory is that differences in the quality of governance measured by these characteristics will correlate with performance in economic development. We will see that the evidence provides at best very weak support for this prediction. There are at two related theoretical problems with this view of market-led development that are stressed in the growth-enhancing view. First, the historical evidence (some of it discussed below) shows that it is extremely difficult if not impossible to achieve these governance conditions in poor countries. In terms of economic theory, this observation is not surprising. Each of these goals, such as the reduction of corruption, the achievement of stable property rights and of an effective rule of law requires significant expenditures of public resources. Poor economies do not have the required fiscal resources and requiring them to achieve these goals before economic development takes off faces a serious problem of sequencing (Khan, 2005). It is not surprising that developing countries do not generally satisfy the market-enhancing governance criteria at early stages of development even in the high-growth cases. Thus, critically important resource re-allocations that are required at early stages of development are unlikely to happen through the market mechanism alone. Not surprisingly, a significant part of the asset and resource re-allocations necessary for accelerating development in developing countries have taken place through semi-market or entirely non-market processes. These processes have been very diverse. Examples include the English Enclosures from the sixteenth to the eighteenth centuries; the creation of the chaebol in South Korea in the 1960s using public resources; the creation of the Chinese “town village enterprises” (TVEs) using public resources in the 1980s and their privatization in the 1990s; and the allocation and appropriation of public land and resources for development in Thailand. Successful developers have displayed a range of institutional and political capacities that enabled semi-market and non-market asset and property right re-allocations that were growth enhancing. In contrast, in less successful developers, the absence of necessary governance capabilities meant that nonmarket transfers descended more frequently into predatory expropriation that impeded development.

Secondly, even reasonably efficient markets face significant market failures in the process of organizing learning to overcome low productivity in late developers (Khan, 2000). Growth in developing countries requires catching up through the acquisition of new technologies and learning to use these new technologies rapidly. Relying only on efficient markets to attract capital and new technologies is inadequate given that efficient markets will attract capital and technology to countries where these technologies are already profitable because the requirement skills of workers and managers already exist. Developing countries have lower technological capabilities and therefore lower labor productivity in most sectors compared to advanced countries, but as against this, they also have lower wages. If markets are efficient, capital will flow to sectors and countries where the wage advantage outweighs the productivity disadvantage. However, for many mid to high-technology sectors in developing countries, the productivity gap remains larger than the wage gap. This explains why most developing countries specialize in low technology sectors and why this specialization would not change rapidly if markets became somewhat more efficient. However, if developing countries could accelerate learning, and therefore productivity growth in mid to high-technology sectors, this would amount to an acceleration of the pace of development. Rapid catching up therefore typically requires some strategy of targeted technology acquisition that allows the follower country to catch up rapidly with leader countries. However, technology-acquisition strategies have been remarkably diverse and high-growth countries have used very different variants of growth enhancing governance that allowed the acceleration of social productivity growth. Thus, not only are markets unlikely to become very efficient in developing countries, even relatively efficient markets would not necessarily help overcome some of the critical problems constraining rapid catching up in developing countries. To the extent that productivity growth depends on better resource allocation, improving market efficiency is clearly desirable. But sustained productivity growth depends on the creation of new technologies or (in the case of developing countries), learning to use existing technologies effectively. Markets by themselves are not sufficient to ensure that productivity growth will be rapid unless appropriate incentives and compulsions exist to induce the creation of new technologies or the learning of old ones. While technical progress is possible along the trajectory set by a market-driven strategy, the climb up the technology ladder is likely to be slower through diffusion and spontaneous learning compared to an active technology acquisition and learning strategy. But to achieve growth faster than that possible through spontaneous learning and technology diffusion, states have to possess the appropriate governance capabilities both to create additional incentives (rents) for investments in advanced technologies that would not otherwise have taken place but also to ensure that non-performers in these sectors do not succeed in retaining the implicit rents. The creation and management of incentives by states in developing countries has been very diverse. In many developing countries, import substituting industrialization attempted to leapfrog technological levels by protecting domestic private or public sector enterprises. But the absence of credible commitments to withdraw support in case of failure and of adequate institutions to assist technology acquisition and learning meant that in most cases, the results were inefficient public and private sector firms that never grew up. Successful countries used many policies that appear superficially similar, including tariff protection, direct subsidies (in particular in South Korea), subsidized and prioritized infrastructure for priority sectors (in China and Malaysia), and subsidizing the licensing of advanced foreign technologies. But while the mechanisms used in many less successful developers appear similar to the ones on this list, there were significant differences in the governance capacities for successfully implementing growth-enhancing strategies.

2.3 Relationship between Good Governance and Economic Growth

Numbers of economists of development consider that good governance, defined as the quality management and orientation of development policies has a positive influence on economic performance. The question is what content the literature gives to the concept of governance? According to the World Bank, good governance is evaluated by the implementation capacity of governance principles of a country, providing a framework for market development and economic growth (Mira & Hammadache, 2017). However, a good governance policy is allows developing countries to achieve minimum economic growth and political reforms in order to reach a level of development similar to that of industrialized countries? We focus on the definition and the work on the concept of good governance made by the World Bank and criticism that reconstructed the notion of governance in a broader sense, taking into account the capacity of states to drive structural change in institutional, political, economic and social fields, in order to ensure long-term economic growth.

Economically, the proper functioning of markets is correlated to the proper functioning of institutions through efficient practice of state governance, what is commonly called” good governance”. Therefore, underdevelopment and low economic growth performance of countries could be explained by a ”state failure” and the components of good governance with the increase in corruption, instability of property rights, market distortions, and lack of democracy (Mira & Hammadache, 2017). The transition of developing countries towards a capitalist system comparable to that of developed countries, cannot operate without the establishment of efficient institutions in relation with distribution of political power in these countries.

Conversely, those countries would face a state failure, as a result of a mismatch between institutions and economic policy for development. The research consists first to present the results of an empirical model that we have done based on a panel of developing countries chosen by region (MENA, Latin America, and Asia) and due to their natural resource endowment. The aim is to check if growth rate may or may not be correlated with good governance indicators as defined by the World Bank (Fayissa & Nsiah, 2013). The goal is to lead in a second time an analysis of criticism made by Mushtaq Khan on the definition of governance, the causes of state failure and barriers to economic development.

Our contribution is to discuss the concept of good governance and the failure of states that take into account the level of development and governance capacity that is based on a structure and distribution of political power that evolves in time and may or may not be positive for growth. The assumption we make here is that the so-called good governance policies are relevant if countries reach a sound level of economic and social development that enable institutions of good governance to boost growth.

2.3.1: Democracy and Economic Development

Not only are political institutions necessary for economic development more likely to exist and function effectively under democratic rule, but also the adaptive efficiencies are best sustained in democracies because institution building to promote good governance and economic development is conterminous with democracy. It is no accident that countries that have reached the highest level of economic performance across generations are all stable democracies. Today, liberal democracy justifiably enjoys near-universal appeal and is regarded as the ideal system of government. According to the “procedural minimum,” liberal democracy is a form of government by means of which citizens, through open and free institutional arrangements, are empowered to choose and remove leaders in a competitive struggle for the people’s vote. According to Robert Dahl, the dean of democratic studies, a truly representative democratic government must be based on the principles of popular sovereignty; competitive political participation and representation; an independent judiciary; free, fair and regular elections; universal suffrage; freedom of expression and conscience; the universal right to form political associations and participate in the political community; inclusive citizenship; and adherence to the constitution and the rule of law. Scholars have long argued that democracies have embedded institutional advantages that support economic development. According to Nobel laureate Amartya Sen, democracies enrich individual lives through the granting of political and civil rights, and do a better job in improving the welfare of the poor, compared to alternative political systems. Second, they provide political incentives to rulers to respond positively to the needs and demands of the people. That is, democracies are seen to be responsive to the demands and pressures from the citizenry, since the right to rule is derived from popular support manifested in competitive elections-or as Robert Dahl long ago noted: governmental responsiveness to citizens’ demands is built into periodically held electoral contests guaranteed by juridically protected individual rights. No doubt, the experiences of the proverbial developmental states of East Asia (Singapore, South Korea, and Taiwan) offer evidence that efficacious state capacity and good governance can be achieved in developmental authoritarian regimes-albeit, not in predatory authoritarian systems. Yet, it is also recognized that authoritarian regimes that are “developmental” are an exception rather than the rule, as authoritarian regimes are more conterminous with pathologies such as predation and expropriation. Minxin Pei makes precisely such a case with reference to the PRC-which at first glance has all the attributes of a developmental state, but is not. Pei’s examination of the sustainability of the Chinese Communist Party’s developmental strategy-that of pursuing pro-market economic policies under dictatorial one-party rule leads him to a number of novel conclusions. Perhaps, most provocatively, Pei refutes the conventional view which sees the Chinese model as reminiscent of the East Asian “developmental state.” Moreover, democracies, unlike authoritarian regimes, offer a better long-term protection of property rights as well as individual and collective freedoms. Indeed, Robert Barro’s cross-country study finds only three former dictatorships in the world (Chile, Singapore, and South Korea) that had not engaged in any expropriation. Also, as noted, recent research on the authoritarian legacies in East Asia has questioned the “human developmental outcomes” of these developmental states. David Kang’s important book, Crony Capitalism: Corruption and Development in South Korea and the Philippines, compelling shows that authoritarian regimes, including the erstwhile developmental ones such as South Korea-once they were well-entrenched-rarely showed any concern for the greater public good and long-term growth.

Contrary to popular belief, under authoritarian rule, health care accessibility was piecemeal and “health care policy outcomes far from universal.” However, Wong notes that the transition toward democracy in both countries dramatically changed the political imperatives of social policy reform. Vote-seeking politicians needing to promote popular policies aligned themselves with health-care reform advocates, including grass-roots activists, to push top-level bureaucrats to implement reformist programs and policies. The end result is that there is a qualitative difference between health care (including other welfare measures) under authoritarian rule and since democratization. In Wong’s view, greater democratic participation in Taiwan and South Korea literally has led to a revision of the social contract between the state and popular classes. His research underscores how democratic political competition in South Korea and Taiwan has compelled the state to redirect its energy away from simply narrow conceptions of economic development (meaning rapid industrialization) to address quality-of-life issues such as health care and education, among other welfare-enhancing measures.

Evidence from a poor democracy such as India is also illustrative. Jenkins claims that, in practice, the Indian state has a far greater degree of autonomy than is assumed by theorists who claim that a democratic state can be easily compromised and captured by particularistic groups, lobbies, dominant-class coalitions, and other vested interests. To the contrary, he argues that India’s “real” functioning democratic state (unlike the idealist theoretical conceptions of it) is actually made up of a rather loose, fluid, and frequently changing conglomeration of interest groups. This reality on the ground gives the state much flexibility and autonomy over policy issues. According to Jenkins, nothing underscores this more vividly than the introduction of economic reforms in 1991 and their continued sustainability. He asks (1) why and how India’s governing elite, long-wedded to a statist-cum-protectionist economic program, suddenly abandoned this in favor of integrating India into the global economic system; (2) how the governing elite succeeded in “selling the benefits of reform to individual constituencies and the public at large,” and (3) how the elite went about implementing their ambitious economic reform agenda. To Jenkins, the answers to these questions lie in appreciating the mechanisms under which “real democracy” functions in India-which he argues can best be understood as “incentives,” “institutions,” and “skills.” With regard to incentives, India’s mercurial political elites are willing to take risks (i.e., to introduce reforms) because they have correctly calculated that reforms will not endanger their political and electoral survival. They know the rules of the game well enough to develop new avenues for collecting rents, distributing patronage, and, given the highly fluid and fragmented nature of interest groups, creating new coalitions for reform, including dividing and isolating interests opposed to reform. Similarly, India’s political institutions, both formal (federal structure) and informal (political party networks), work in ways that help the political elites to implement reforms with surprising ease.

2.4 Good Governance Explained

Firstly, good governance means strong government capacity, namely, local government has enough resources, such as manpower and financial resources; to improve the capital market and investment climate; to keep the bureaucratic system stable and maintain bureaucratic professionalization; to develop a good economic power structure and political power structure; to promote system reform in all fields like science and technology; and to provide public services like medical treatment and education, which facilitates industrial upgrading and economic growth, resulting in strengthening the “helping hand” of government power (Fayissa & Nsiah, 2013).

The Nature of Governance

The Nature of Governance The root of the word governance, like government, is a word related to steering a boat. A steering metaphor is indeed a good way in which to approach the idea of governance in contemporary societies. Societies require collective choices about a range of issues that cannot be addressed adequately by individual action, and some means much be found to make and to implement those decisions. The need for these collective decisions has become all the more obvious when the world as a whole, as well as individual societies, are faced with challenges such as climate change, resource depletion. and arms control that cannot be addressed by individual actions, and indeed are often cases in which individual self-interest is likely to result in collective harm (Hardin, 1977; Ostrom, 1990). Governance also implies some conception of accountability so that the actors involved in setting goals and then in attempting to reach them, whether through public or private action, must be held accountable for their actions (Van Keersbergen and Van Waarden, 2004) to society.

Effective governance, except in very rare exceptions, therefore, may be better provided with the involvement of State actors, and hence governance is an essentially political concept, and one that requires thinking about the forms of public action. The tendency of some contemporary theories of governance to read the State out of that central position in governance therefore appear misguided. Just as more traditional versions of governance that excluded non-State actors ignored a good deal of importance in governing so too would any conception–academic or practical–that excluded the State from a central role. There are a variety of ways in which these collective problems associated in governance can be addressed. Scholars have advanced some rather important arguments that autonomous action through voluntary agreements can solve these problems (Ostrom, 2005; Lam, 1998). This style of solving collective action problems is important but may depend upon special conditions, and perhaps on factors such as leadership.

In addition to the monopoly of legitimate force, governments also have ex ante rules for making decisions. At the most basic level these are constitutions (Sartori, 1994) and then there are rules and procedures within public institutions that enable them to make decisions in the face of conflicts. Although many of the social mechanisms that have been central in thinking about governance may be able to involve a range of actors but these mechanisms may encounter difficulties in reaching decisions, and especially in teaching high quality decisions (but see Klijn and Koppenjanns, 2004). Lacking ex ante decision rules, networks and analogous structures must bargain to consensus through some means or another. This style of decision-making may appear democratic but it is also slow and tends to result in poor decisions. Others argue concerning systems in which all actors have de facto vetoes outcomes tend to be by the lowest common denominator, so that highly innovative and potentially controversial decisions are unlikely to emerge. This “joint decision trap” can be overcome in part by recognizing the iterative nature of decisions and by the capacity of actors involved to build package deals that enable them to overcome marked differences in preferences.

Effective government matters, but what is it? Good governance indicators go some way to provide a definition, but how much do they say about what effectiveness is, why this is so, and how it matters to development? This article argues that much work on the good governance agenda suggests a one-best-way model, ostensibly of an idyllic, developed country government: Sweden or Denmark on a good day, perhaps. The implied model lacks consistency, however, seems inappropriate for use in the development dialogue and is not easily replicated. In short, it resembles a set of well meaning but problematic proverbs. The good governance picture of effective government is not only of limited use in development policy but also threatens to promote dangerous isomorphism, institutional dualism and “flailing states”. It imposes an inappropriate model of government that “kicks away the ladder” that today's effective governments climbed to reach their current states. The model's major weakness lies in the lack of an effective underlying theoretical framework to assist in understanding government roles and structures in development. A framework is needed before we measure government effectiveness or propose specific models of what government should look like. Given the evidence of multiple states of development, the idea of a one-best-way model actually seems very problematic.

Additionally, China’s economy has the characteristics of transition and development, which may bring market absence and market failure, resulting in a negative impact on local economic growth. Therefore, local governments must play an important role in economic growth to weaken the “grabbing hand” of market power.

Secondly, good governance also means that market mechanism plays a key role in resource allocation, which can make full use of local comparative advantages, and strengthen the market competitiveness of products, resulting in the expansion of the market share of enterprise and the scale of industry, and the rapid growth of the local economy in China (Fayissa & Nsiah, 2013). Therefore, we define the positive effect of the market on economic growth as the “helping hand” of market power. At the same time, the full development of local market economy not only supports the “helping hand” of government power by providing tax, products, and services, among others, but also weakens the “grabbing hand” of government power by forcing the local government to gradually reduce the intervention.

Thirdly, good governance also means rule of law, that is, market subjects and government entities are forbidden to act as the “grabbing hand” and are encouraged to be the “helping hand” by legal institutions, they are willing to act in strict accordance with the law, none of them have the privilege to overstep the Constitution and other laws. Rule of law belongs to the software infrastructure, and has an important impact on local economic growth by institutionalization (Fayissa & Nsiah, 2013). For example, through the protection of private property rights, rule of law weakens the “grabbing hand” of government power, and strengthens the “helping hand” of market power; through the protection of intellectual property rights, rule of law relieves the “grabbing hand” of market power, and encourages the “helping hand” of market.

Political Change and Governance Outcomes

The arguments pointing to the efficacy of elections are intuitively appealing. The lower the cost to citizens of expelling non-performing officials, the more we would expect officials to act in the interests of citizens. In practice, however, electoral markets are often highly imperfect, disrupting electoral accountability and the ability of citizens to sanction governments that allow poor governance outcomes to persist. One key political market imperfection is uninformed citizens. If citizens cannot draw a connection between public policy and their own welfare, neither elections nor other, non-electoral means of expelling politicians easily limit governance abuses by government officials. Citizens may not understand the relationship between political decision making and their welfare, perhaps because of substantial delay between government actions and welfare changes (for example, banking crises triggered by corrupt financial sector regulation may not emerge until years after corrupt regulatory decisions are made); or shocks cloud the ability of citizens to assess political contributions to their welfare. India experienced a number of significant shocks in the 1970s that had this effect. A second political market imperfection arises when the promises of politicians are not credible. For example, if the leaders of non-elite parties cannot credibly promise to non-elites that they will refrain from expropriating non-elite investments, the introduction of elections in unequal societies does not necessarily result in faster growth. Parties struggle to build reputations for preferring particular policies or for serving particular groups of citizens better than their opponents. When political competitors cannot make broad promises, they resort to appeals to those narrow groups of citizens to whom they can make credible promises—but when those groups are narrow, incentives to improve governance for all citizens dwindle (Keefer and Vlaicu 2005). An important aspect of the political history of India that underlies changes in the governance environment is the emergence of credible political challenges to the Congress Party. Political market imperfections are more acute in countries beset by deprivation or profound social polarization. Isolated and poor populations are less likely to know of the relationship between political actions and the governance environment, or to appreciate the importance of the country’s governance environment for their own personal well-being. Similarly, in countries riven by social tension, the costs of making credible political promises to all citizens dwarf those of making promises targeted to individual groups. Each political competitor belongs to one of the groups and is therefore mistrusted by all the others. Political checks and balances also play a significant role in improving governance outcomes. They limit the ability of narrowly focused parties or individual decision makers to act unilaterally in their own interests. Efforts to divert resources for private benefit, or to expropriate some citizens to favor others, are all more difficult in the presence of political checks and balances. More obviously, political checks and balances limit the chances that any one leader will embark on disastrous policy experiments. Regardless of whether they face competitive elections, political leaders pursue good governance outcomes to the extent that it helps them remain in office. If improving the economic welfare of all citizens is a cornerstone of the leadership’s political strategy in a country without competitive elections, then the leadership has a strong incentive to pursue good governance. They can do this if they build a large ruling party and develop intra-party institutions that allow them to make credible promises to party members. The logic here is straightforward: government leaders cannot convince average citizens that they will not expropriate their investments, since average citizens have no easy way to punish such expropriation. However, if government leaders can make credible promises to party members, the larger the number of party members, the greater is investment, and the greater is the demand for the labor of average citizens. The key change in China from the 1970s to the 1980s was the introduction of institutions that constrained the discretion of the top leadership towards the large membership of the Communist Party. Large parties, organized to protect members from arbitrary decisions by the party leadership, are costly for leaders to establish; hence, their rarity (Gehlbach and Keefer 2006). For example, a necessary condition for party member loyalty is that members receive larger rents than they could outside the party. As their number rises, so too does the share of rents party members as a whole receive. All of the intra-party institutions that make promises to party members credible also require leaders to surrender rents. Intra-party checks and balances reduce the rent share of any individual leader. Investments in elaborate intra-party evaluation and promotion processes, such as those China introduced in the 1970s and 1980s, enhance credibility, since the investments are lost if the criteria are violated. They also are expensive. Regular turnover of the party leadership and rule-based succession improves the credibility of leaders, but these obviously reduce the share of rents that flows to party leaders. Institutionalized parties in settings without competitive elections are therefore less likely where large rents can be extracted from little investment; President Sese Mobutu, for example, made no attempt to create a broad-based, institutionalized political party in Zaire, choosing instead to personalize government and to treat even close supporters unpredictably. The huge rents available from natural resources (copper) explain this strategy: the gains from credibility (higher rents from productive investment) were offset by the natural resource rents he would have lost if he had had to share them with a broad, institutionalized party. Power sharing is also less likely when a single leader of the unelected government commands disproportionately more influence (military, popular or otherwise) than the others. When this is not the case, political checks and balances emerge naturally, as the consequence of a balance of power among key leaders. When the distribution of power within the leadership group is unbalanced, as in China under Mao Zedong, political checks and balances are difficult to establish.

2.5 Service Delivery Theories 2.5.1 The Shared Governance Theory

The theory of shared governance is best demonstrated when he wrote about the desired need to reorganize Canadian health care institutions. In his study, Anthony argued that one of the early but enduring goals of the shared governance theory was to improve the work environment of nurses, their satisfaction, and retention (Fan & Zietsma, 2017). A number of pre/post shared governance implementation studies demonstrate their effect on the work environment. Historically, the theoretical underpinnings of the shared governance seem to have been anchored on a broad set of perspectives that included organizational, management, and sociological theories.

Understanding the variation in these theoretical viewpoints helps us to appreciate the history of how the shared governance theory was designed and implemented. The earliest foundation for shared governance arose from the human resource era of organizational theories. This era represented the first departure from the traditions of scientific management. Theorists such as Herzberg in 1966 and McGregor in 1960 championed employees as an organization’s most important asset encouraging 17 organizations to invest in employee motivation and growth (Fan & Zietsma, 2017). From the human resource era emerged business and management philosophies that directly influenced the development of the shared governance model. It has influenced broader redesign initiatives that emphasize performance.

A critical examination of the shared governance theory reveals that its tenets are so similar to the fundamentals on which public participation is anchored. Practicing the shared governance theory seems to suggest that it leads to an accrual of greater performance benefits of organizations and a significantly improved work environment (He, Eden & Hitt, 2016). This theory, therefore, is a great anchor of this study on public participation within the discourse of devolution in Kenya. The belief that large and monopolistic public bureaucracies are inherently inefficient was a critical force driving the emergence of the new public management. The theory represents a set of ideas, values and practices aimed at emulating private sector practices in the public sector.

Recently, there was a need to reinvent government and harness the entrepreneurial spirit to transform the public sector and later “banish the bureaucracy”. The new public management theory takes its intellectual foundations from public choice theory, which looks at government from the standpoint of markets and productivity, and from managerialism, which focuses on management approaches to achieve productivity gains (He, Eden & Hitt, 2016). The three underlying issues which new public management theory attempts to resolve includes: citizen-centered services; value for taxpayers’ money and a responsive public service workforce.

Notably, there are also studies that indicate that the new public management reforms do not necessarily lead to 18 improved service deliveries. The new public management is often mentioned together with governance. Governance is about setting up of structure of government and of overall strategy, while new public management is the operational aspect of the new type of public administration. The theory has also been supported by individuals who contend that the dominant theme of new public management is the use of market techniques to improve the performance of the public sector.

The main features of new public management include performance management, e-governance, contracting out and outsourcing, decentralization and accountability among others. The proponents of this theory advocates that the government should put in place social accountability mechanisms to increase efficiency in service delivery. The new public management theory is relevant to the current study as it informs public participation, social accountability practices and service delivery variables (Pollitt & Bouckaert, 2017). The theory advocates for citizens participation in the process of evaluating public services since the new public management principle of customer responsiveness requires that the degree of the user satisfaction be measured.

This study drew from the theory of new public management in understanding the impact of social accountability on service delivery. The broad idea of new public management theory, is the use of market mechanisms in the public sector to make managers and providers more responsive and accountable (Pollitt & Bouckaert, 2017). The theory is also important in understanding the service delivery variable. The rationale of establishing county governments is to ensure efficient service delivery. In this regard, county governments are important tool for new public management reforms in improving the quality public services and increasing the efficiency of governmental operations.

The new public management theory is, therefore, evident in the quality of services delivered by the county governments and is a great anchor of this study (Schwartz, 2017). This theory refers to measures that are designed to improve the overall performance of an organization (as a composition of sub-systems) by increasing its effectiveness and legitimacy. It advocates for the establishment of a solid foundation for management structures, public participation, policies and procedures which help institutions to fulfill their set goals. Although, this could lead to legal challenges, delays and cost to decisions, applying the governance theory in the management of devolved systems ensures full participation of all the stakeholders and sectors within the devolved governance systems (Schwartz, 2017).

2.5.2 Government Functional Requirements

Goal Selection

Governing is steering and steering requires some knowledge about the destination toward which one is steering. This function can be performed by State actors along but also may involve social actors. We do need to remember, however, that goals are not simple, and exist at a variety of levels ranging from broad goals such as “social justice” down to operational goals of departments and programs. Therefore, effective governance requires the integration of goals across all levels of the systems.

Goal Reconciliation and Coordination

The multiple actors within government all have their own goals, and effective governance therefore requires establishing some priorities and coordinating the actions taken according to those priorities.

Implementation

The decisions made in the first two stages of the process above must then be put into effect, requiring some form of implementation. This stage of the process is more likely to can be performed by State actors along but also may involve social actors. A successful implementation calls for a proper governance and leadership that is mandated to execute the deliberations to its latter form.

Feedback and Accountability

Finally, individuals and institutions involved in governance need to learn from their actions. This is important both for improving the quality of the decisions being made and also important for democratic accountability. Therefore, some well-developed method of feedback must be built into the governance arrangements. These functions are rather basic to the process of governance, and can be elaborated further by considering the processes involved, such as decision-making, resource mobilization, implementation and adjudication. The functions themselves may be excessively broadly conceived, but the process elements involved in them can be detailed to a much greater extent and can also be related to many processes discussed in other areas of political science.

2.6 Conflict Theory

Any political system revolves around conflict. A study observed that conflict is a struggle over values and claim to scarce resources, services, power and resources (Rupesinghe, 2016). The author further observed that conflict, between inter groups and intra groups are part of social life and is part of relationship building and not necessarily a sign of instability. It is worth noting at this point that all cases that involve people from diverse backgrounds, social and political beliefs necessarily witness levels of conflict (Rupesinghe, 2016). However, there are positive effects of conflict which include; the development of a sense of identity, priority setting and provision of legitimate ground for organizing and seeking preventive measures, management and conflict resolution approaches.

In this context, conflict serves as a lens to monitor institutional and government activities whose target beneficiaries are the citizens. According to Rupesinghe (2016), conflict is the main feature of partnership experienced between the government, private sector and nonprofit centers.

Conflict management has become a major source of concern. These conflicts can affect the county government decision-making process due to public servants’ personal or private interests. The process can be affected either positively or negatively.

The assessment of public understanding on devolution is essential in the development process. Misunderstanding on devolution leads to low expectations on leaders as well as low participation by the public. This obviously creates a gap between the public and the leaders in the society thereby a challenge in the development process (Lubell, Mewhirter, Berardo & Scholz, 2019). On the other hand, understanding leads to high expectations from the leaders and raises participation of the public in the development process. Positive effects of conflict are highlighted and include developing a sense of identity, priorities setting and provision of legitimate ground for organizing, seek preventive measures, management and resolution systems (Lubell, Mewhirter, Berardo & Scholz, 2019). Although conflicts among citizen is a major source of due to personal vested interest it should be closely monitored to avoid stifling performance and it is not necessarily a sign of instability and is part of relationship building hence the application of the theory to boost performance in the devolved governance systems.

2.7 Feedback Mechanisms Theories 2.7.1 The Citizen Involvement Theory

Citizen participation is a process which provides individuals an opportunity to influence public decision-making process. The roots of citizen participation can be traced to ancient Greece and Colonial New England. Before the 1960s, governmental processes and procedures were designed to facilitate external participation. Citizen participation was institutionalized in the mid1960s with President Lyndon Johnson’s Great Society Programs (Beresford & Croft, 2016).

Democratic decision-making in contrast to bureaucratic or technocratic decision making is based on the assumption that all who are affected by a given decision have the right to participate in the making of that decision. Participation can be direct in the classical democratic sense, or can be through representatives for their 21 point of view in a pluralist-republican model (Beresford & Croft, 2016). In a democracy, it is the public that determines the direction to go and their representatives and bureaucratic staff role is to get them there. This means the end should be chosen democratically even though the means are chosen technocratically. Although many government agencies or individuals choose to exclude or minimize public participation in planning efforts claiming citizen participation is too expensive and time consuming (Beresford & Croft, 2016). Yet, many citizen participation programs are initiated in response to public reaction to a proposed project or action.

A successful citizen participation program must be: integral to the planning process and focused on its unique needs; designed to function within available resources of time, personnel, and money; and responsive to the citizen participants (Beresford & Croft, 2016). At a practical level, public consultation programs should strive to isolate and make visible the extremes. The program should therefore create incentives for participants to find a middle ground. This theory instigates public participation as an influence of performance of devolved governance systems in Kenya. 2.8 The Communication Development Theory Development

Communication is an educational process. It aims at developing social consciousness, personal responsibility towards one’s fellowmen, one’s community and country. In other words, it is a social conscience hence sensitizing the conscience. Beunen, Van Assche & Duineveld (2016) imply development communication as respect for the human person, respect for his intelligence and his right to self-determination. Development communication help organization to engage the community as a stakeholder in educative and awareness issues and this helps to establish conducive working environment for assessing risks and opportunities and promotes information exchanges to bring about positive social change via sustainable development (Beunen, Van Assche & Duineveld, 2016). Development communication implies respect for the human person, respect for his intelligence and his right to self-determination.

The role of mass communication is to help, not to take over or substitute for, his thinking. It serves him by providing the facts on which to base a sound judgment, and the inspiration to carry out his resolve (Flew, Martin & Suzor, 2019). Thus, development communication is a social process because it seeks the human response of people in society. The term “social communication”, therefore, suggests the primacy of human values and human dignity over mere technique, better than “mass communication”. It is the mark of human beings to be social, whereas the concept of mass is derived from an obvious quality of brute matter.

Flew, Martin & Suzor, (2019), point out that development communication technique such as information dissemination and education, behaviour change, social marketing, social mobilization, media advocacy, communication for social change and community participation has helped many organizations with development agenda to succeed even in the phase of hostility if the techniques are well used. The theory of development communication is therefore important to this study as it demonstrates the extent to which feedback mechanisms through proper communication influences performance of devolved governance in the devolved systems.

Public Participation Conceptually, public participation is an appealing model that promotes the ideals of shared governance of institutions. Public participation, transparency, and accountability in decision-making processes are paramount for public service delivery and efficiency (Ríos, Benito & Bastida, 2017). Kenya’s constitution and the legal framework on devolution place strong emphasis on public participation, transparency, and accountability as means of improving efficiency, equity, and inclusiveness of government and service delivery. Multiple studies have documented how governance weaknesses limit Kenya’s economic and social development and impede its progress toward national goals for economic growth, job creation, social inclusion, equity, and poverty reduction.

Devolution creates a new opportunity, as well as new challenges, for addressing governance challenges that limit the efficiency and equity of service delivery. Evidence is mounting that strengthening public participation is critical for effective service delivery. However, devolution alone does not necessarily improve the accountability and responsiveness of service delivery, unless proper accountability mechanisms, such as public participation are instituted (Ríos, Benito & Bastida, 2017). Based on the 2010 Kenyan constitution, there are six key benefits of engaging in public participation processes; namely, it strengthens democracy and governance; by engaging in public participation in policy, law and development of policy processes, the public exercise their constitutional rights, and as a result, the decision making process becomes more representative (Ríos, Benito & Bastida, 2017).

Openness to the public provides a platform in which the public presents their concerns and engages with government. Insufficient public engagement limits the power of the people to participate in democratic governance; public participation increases accountability; improves transparency and accountability of the social, political, cultural, economic, and environmental impacts of policies, laws and development plans and of how the costs and benefits impact on different segments of society (Ríos, Benito & Bastida, 2017). Public participation helps to ensure that governments are accountable for their 25 actions and responsive to public interests. By linking the public with decision-makers, public confidence and support of decision making processes is enhanced.

Public participation also improves process quality, enables governments to understand different opinions and concerns and ensures that policies, laws and development plans are more robust because they have been tested through a comprehensive process of review and revision before being approved (Ríos, Benito & Bastida, 2017). It also provides additional skills, knowledge, concerns, and ideas that might not have otherwise been considered. Public participation manages and helps to alleviate social conflicts by bringing different stakeholders and interests together. It also helps in assessing the impact of conflict in reaching a consensus. Investment in public participation at an early stage helps minimize both the number and the magnitude of social conflicts arising over the course of the implementation of policies, laws and development plans.

Public participation enhances process legitimacy, public participation in policy, law and development plans and development legitimizes implementation processes. Ríos, Benito & Bastida (2017) allude that without significant public participation, the public may feel manipulated and suspicious which may undermine effective dialogue and create distrust. Participation also protects public interests. Active public participation can protect public interests, by reducing public conflict and safeguards against future risks. Public Participation as a process provides private individuals an opportunity to influence public decisions and has long been a component of the democratic decision-making process.

The roots of citizen participation can be traced to ancient Greece and Colonial New England. Before the 1960s, governmental processes and procedures were designed to facilitate "external" participation. Citizen participation was institutionalized in the mid 1960s with President Lyndon Johnson's Great Society programs. Public involvement is a means to ensuring that citizens have a direct voice in public decisions.

While the terms "citizen and public" and "involvement and participation" are often used interchangeably, both are generally used to indicate a process through which citizens have a voice in public policy decisions, both have distinctively different meanings and convey little 26 insight into the process they seek to describe (Ríos, Benito & Bastida, 2017). Other scholars assert that the term "citizen participation" and it's relationship to public decision-making has evolved without a general consensus regarding either it's meaning nor its consequences. Many government agencies or individuals choose to exclude or minimize public participation in planning efforts claiming citizen participation is too expensive and time consuming (Ríos, Benito & Bastida, 2017). Yet, many citizen participation programs are initiated in response to public reaction to a proposed project or action. However, there are tangible benefits that can be derived from an effective citizen involvement program. Identify five benefits of citizen participation to the planning process as information and ideas on public issues giving; public support for planning decisions; avoidance of protracted conflicts and costly delays; reservoir of good will which can carry over to future decisions; and spirit of cooperation and trust between the agency and the public.

2.9 Citizen Empowerment

The new Constitution of Kenya laid the basis of county development on citizen participation. However, the key huddles faced by citizens in engaging in meaningful participation and effective development of counties are linked to various needs and duties (Vlachokyriakos, Crivellaro, Le Dantec, Gordon, Wright & Olivier, 2016). The need to create awareness amongst both duty bearers and citizens on what citizen participation is and its importance; the need to build the capacity of citizens to enhance their participation in the management of local affairs and projects, and to hold duty bearers accountable; and the need for duty bearers to engage in continuous capacity building on participatory methodologies.

To engage effectively, citizens not only need an awareness of their roles and responsibilities but knowledge and skills on how to execute the responsibilities. Capacity building consists of developing knowledge, skills and operational capacity so that individuals and groups may achieve their purposes. If citizens are going to participate in planning and administrative processes of government information is central to such participative processes. Hughes argued that participating in managing organizational change, informed citizens will have to resolve the definitional, manageability, evaluating success/failure and predicting the future conundrums that the study of managing change raises for change scholars (Vlachokyriakos, Crivellaro, Le Dantec, Gordon, Wright & Olivier, 2016). One of the key barriers to citizen empowerment is the level of citizen capacity, meaning the abilities of the citizens to engage effectively in partnership activities.

In addition, there is often existence of ‘institutional resistance’ as a barrier to citizen empowerment. This is currently preventing the reform of public services to more fully recognize the role of citizen empowerment and actually implement service redesign and reform of delivery that fully engages with the local populace. Local government models have a long history of centralization rather than ‘double devolution’ and the local government approach to service delivery is grounded in the ethos of public service rather than public participation (Brinkerhoff, & Wetterberg, 2016). For effective engagement of the public in governance matters, the public require multiple empowerment styles, patterns and levels of engagement in order to promote a broad base of citizen participation that underpins regeneration partnerships for improved performance of devolved governance systems.

Research objectives although researchers show that governance can influence on economic growth, there is still much to uncover to ensure governance-related policies are appealing to policymakers. Most importantly, as literature reveals, the relationship between governance and economic growth has not been proved by enough evidence. For the effective policy intervention, it is important to identify the important governance factors that affect on economic growth. Therefore, the goal of this study is to measure the impact of governance on economic growth.

Theoretical relationship between governance and economic growth Governance is a broad and multi-faceted concept. It describes the way that state power is exercised to manage its economic and social components (Brinkerhoff, & Wetterberg, 2016). The manner in which the state exercises its power has a link to a set of institutions that engage as keys to economic growth. There is a set of fundamental institutions needed for economic growth. These institutions include well-defined property rights, unbiased contract enforcements, low information gap between buyers and sellers, and stable macroeconomic conditions.

Emerging democracies in Africa are faced with enormous responsibilities, and the imperative need for direction, unity or approach and authority, a strong and organized civil society which complements a strong efficient central state able to address the needs of different constituencies and interest groups (Brinkerhoff, & Wetterberg, 2016). Conversely, in their fragmented world, transition democracies are confronted with need to reinstate the basic contractual relationship between the state and citizen, to restore weak state institutions, shattered social, political, and cultural foundations and re-establish political trust and legitimacy.

As a consequence, emerging African pluralist system, as in Kenya, is to balance between control and participation, between often times authoritarian past and a dynamic pluralistic future, while with these systems, power has to be re-negotiated among cultural, economic, and spatial segments, avoiding re-segmentation and hold hostilities to flare up (Brinkerhoff, & Wetterberg, 2016). This brings in challenges related to participation and voice, perception of community and ideologies of justice, reconciliation, ethnic re alignment, and eventually a dawning of dynamic participatory, relevant, and reflective democracy.

The idea of decentralization has increasingly gained a new momentum in Kenya within the framework of constitutional review debate and activism. During the single party regime, power was centralized excessively with the presidency dominating and controlling most crucial sectors of the state (Vlachokyriakos, Crivellaro, Le Dantec, Gordon, Wright & Olivier, 2016). Indeed the clamor for review of governance through constitutional change was brought about with the specific purpose of empowering the citizens and developing not democratic state per se but democratic society that practices local governance.

However, as has become apparent in several African countries, the resurgence and resilience of the 'old guard' together with the ever present tension between different ethnic political classes, as well tension between the opening of trans-nationalism and traditional patriarchal village-style logic brought new pressures, mainly felt in the transference of central authority to territorial communities, as decentralization of east while centralized state power enabled local elites to strengthen their role as intermediaries between the locality, the state and international networks, while silencing others.

Thus, zooming in on decentralization and the shaping of local governance in emerging democratic state like Kenya brings into focus significant political challenges, crucially related to the monumental task of deepening the infant multi party democratic dispensation, and going beyond politico-administrative components of state (re) building democratic state institutions and systems (Vlachokyriakos, Crivellaro, Le Dantec, Gordon, Wright & Olivier, 2016). The centre attention of this research is therefore twofold. First, a focus on the position, sources of state legitimacy, and functioning of local government, and of possibly competing institutions like civil society and informal political sectors- in for example restoring the rule of law, protecting social reconstruction objectives, and harmonizing local and national interstates- should give insight in the way the state in the multi party democratic dispensation in Africa takes shape at the local level. Secondly, rather than focusing on state and civil society vis a viz constitutional mechanisms and their role in reconstruction of a democratic society, the study concentrates in the under- researched phenomenon, namely 'ethnic ideologies' of (political) transitions and democratization, through an analysis of 'ethnic politics', identification, notions of governance and community, power, violence and people's voice.

For all its unique features, Kenya represents an interesting case for the examination of African State (re) formation. While there is a strong tradition of political centralization under the colonial then subsequently single party tyranny, power has in reality been, maintained through, and dispersed throughout the state, by tight informal patriarchal and clientalistic informal networks, encompassing much which is more usually thought of as 'non-state' or 'extra -state'. Thus, state and society have never been fully separated contrary to analyses of African political systems focusing on repression and state society divisions (Vlachokyriakos, Crivellaro, Le Dantec, Gordon, Wright & Olivier, 2016). Closely related to this paradigm is the recognition that the majority of Africa's economy is in formalized, and this extends to the political sphere. One may identify centers of power and sources of resilience and trust; alternative to the former political arena that suggests a 'transmogrification' of traditional systems of order.

These characteristic, odd in western eyes, have re-prompted speculations that such forms of organization are in fact 'traditional/ ethnic', indicating a transitional phase, which will eventually lead to a more institutionalized state according to western concepts of 'modernity'. Thus, the convergence of changing international systems with an increasingly informal state has created new possibilities for the projection of power, which analytically challenges political theory.

Moreover, another reason why Kenya provides such interesting occurrence lies in its multi ethnic composition which can be argued as 'multi layered' society, and the different ways in which order, morality, ethnicity and social control were relegated at the local level to smaller, bounded political or moral communities, in the absence of an overarching civic/political culture, reflecting a sequence of initiatives and responses outside challenges. Kenya's democratization process especially since the post 1982 coup attempt on to the 90s activism era to date as depicted as a 'classic' arena ethicized politics and petty interest of the political class (Moskowitz, 2017). The reality of current Kenya politics is however complicated.

For instance, through 1997, 2002 elections and indeed through Kenya Africa National Union Party (KANU) which at its peak in the 1970s, 80s and early 90s represented a largely self reliant organization linked to regional and international political and economic systems- and local populations in specific ethnic strongholds, new, alternative identities were created and shaped, depending more on specific ethnic support in pretext of 'nation-building'. Rather, KANU's ideology of 'Kenyan nationalism' and by extension 'Africanism' was both mirror and consequences of Western hegemony as it served to assert oneself against the urban elite based culturally synthesized cosmopolitan community (Moskowitz, 2017). Thus political violence, ethnic politics and political corruption has served as a relation of power in itself, creating and defining identities and not just as a means of enforcing power.

The novelty of the proposed research lies not only in its subject but also concerns its very site: the need for empirical research in Kenya is as large as ever. Since the existing gaps in knowledge about the country are enormous especially as concerns her quest for stable democratic culture, good governance and the understanding of the central role that ethnicity plays in its state politics compared to the rest of Africa (Moskowitz, 2017).

The research methods to be used are largely qualitative in their nature, such as participant observation, focus group discussion, and interviews during a longer period of fieldwork at the local level. As a preparation for this research, a documentation study and preliminary empirical studies are envisaged, concentrated on policy processes, intervening state and non state actors i.e. civil society, and attending debates and public forums on governance and reconciliation.

The approach is not only multi-sited, recognizing the globalization calls for different research methods, but also interdisciplinary, using concepts of political science, cultural anthropology, and social psychology (Moskowitz, 2017). In this way, the research seeks to contribute to a deeper understanding of current multi party democracy political systems and governance, its role in dispensing justice, rule of law, political reconciliation, and more general, to the dynamic intertwining of politics and more general, to the dynamic intertwining of politics and culture in a changing world order.

2.10 Governance and major growth theories

Political stability, the absence of terrorism and violence, proficient government policy formulation and implementation, improved regulatory mechanisms, reduced corruption and ensuring the rule of law can be recognized as high governance qualities. The utilitarianism theory comes in handy in governance that aims to benefit the people and not a few individuals (Owoye & Onafowora, 2017). The theory advocates for doing good in the process of leadership in order to render benefits to the subjects.

The provision of accomplished governance leads to improvement in the institutions mentioned above. The increase in economic growth as a result of the high quality of institutions can be directly and indirectly explained by using the Solow model, new growth theory and social infrastructure view (Owoye & Onafowora, 2017). The better quality institutions can contribute to the Solow model by increasing the availability of technology. It is clear that any form of bad governance, such as high political violence, terrorism and widespread corruption hurts citizens mentally and physically by decreasing their productivity.

Then, it is reasonable to assume that better governance removes these physical and mental constraints and as a result, labour productivity improves. Then, this technological improvement acts to increase economic growth through encouraging capital accumulation. In another view, the improved institutions provide a conducive environment for investors. In this argument, it follows that increased investment is made in physical and human capital development (Owoye & Onafowora, 2017). Human capital development includes the knowledge, abilities and skills that are acquired by the individual worker through the learning process and it results in an increase in the output per worker.

On the other hand, increased investments in the physical capital increases capital per worker compared with the initial condition. These approaches eventually lead economic growth through the process of capital accumulation. New growth theory identifies the role of technology as a driving force for economic growth. The technological progress increases along with the rate of knowledge accumulation. In this model, research and development generates knowledge and favorable institutions such as property rights promote investment in research and development and thereby contribute to economic growth (Owoye & Onafowora, 2017). In commenting on the Solow model, argue that only a part of the output per worker can be explained using physical capital accumulation and the learning achievements of workers.

The significant contribution to the remaining part of the cross-country differences in per-worker output carries the policy and institutional differences across countries. In addition, the importance of institutions and government policies in economic growth occurs in various perspectives. According to this theory, better governance creates the favorable institutions and government policies that encourage investment and production. A higher level of investment in human capital and physical capital causes economic growth.

On the other hand, better institutions and government policies allocate 6 a country’s valuable resources for production instead of diversion. Allocation of a country’s resources for investment and production causes an increase in the future output points out two pathways requiring consideration for the study of economic growth: growth over time and regional disparity.

The Solow model and new growth theory can explain the growth over time (Owoye & Onafowora, 2017). However, these neoclassical growth models have a weakness in explaining the regional disparity in the world. Although the concept of social infrastructure has a higher potential to provide a better explanation for the regional differences, there is an insufficient number of quality studies available in this area. However, as explained above, better governance can provide favorable economic conditions for technological progress, along with the human and physical capital formation that is key to economic growth (Owoye & Onafowora, 2017). Corruption and economic growth Corruption means selling of the organization’s resources, exclusive information and decision-making power by a government party to a non-government party.

In the corruption action, there is a supply arising from the government party and a demand arising from the non-government party argues, people have a different understanding of the impact of governance on economic growth. One group believes (Sanders) that the corruption has a negative effect on economic growth because it increases the transaction cost and the production cost (Owoye & Onafowora, 2017). Most importantly, the corruption will decrease the consumer confidence and investor confidence and, degenerate the trust of the society.

Finally, higher corruption causes a reduction in the overall institutional quality of the particular society. Bureaucrats can seek bribes by using their authority to delay decisions. Second, the officers who administer taxes have authority to make decisions on tax incentives, tax liabilities and the implementation of relevant regulations. This power allows them to engage in rent-seeking activities.

Governance Summarized

It has been observed that it is the quality of governance and not the type of political regime that has made the difference in the economic performance of Asian countries. Project evaluations conducted by the Asian Development Bank and the World Bank show that the project performance of countries are largely determined by the overall capacity for administration or implementation. These findings would seem to indicate the significance of the non-political and functional elements in the strategic interactions between government and citizens. Moreover, they highlight these fundamentals: accountability, transparency and predictability (Root, 1995). In like manner, the World Bank emphasizes four dimensions of governance: capacity and efficiency of the public sector, accountability, legal framework for development, and transparency and information. On the other hand, scholars include the following as the critical elements that make up good governance: political and bureaucratic accountability, freedom of association, objective and efficient judiciary, freedom of information and expression, and efficient public institutions. Meanwhile, Huther and Shah (1998) consider four observable aspects of governance: citizen exit and voice, government orientation (judicial efficiency, bureaucratic efficiency and lack of corruption), social development (i.e., human development in the tradition of UNDP plus equity) and economic management. Accountability, Participation. Accountability holds public officials responsible for government behavior and makes it imperative for them to be responsive to the needs of the citizenry. At the local level, it refers to the flexibility of structures that would allow beneficiaries to improve program/project design and implementation. It also entails the establishment of criteria to measure the performance of local officials and the creation of oversight mechanisms to ensure that standards are met. Accountability may be obtained at two levels: macro-level accountability and micro-level accountability (Paul 1991, World Bank 1992). Macro-level accountability refers to the system whereby ministers are accountable to the legislature and/or political leadership and whereby civil servants are accountable to the ministers. As such, it has two main aspects: financial accountability and economic accountability. On the one hand, financial accountability involves: "a properly functioning government accounting system for effective expenditure control and cash management; an external audit system which reinforces expenditure control by exposure and sanctions against mis-spending and corruption; and mechanisms to review and act on the results of audits and to ensure that follow-up action is taken to remedy problems identified (World Bank 1992). On the other hand, economic accountability refers to the evaluation and monitoring of efficient use of resources in government. It may be reflected in performance contracts, memorandums of understanding, value for money audits and legislative review of ministry or department activities. Macro-level accountability may be promoted by: making comprehensive and timely information available; classifying expenditures in a manner consistent with budget programs; doing appropriate analyses for decision making; comparing budgets with results; improving the organization and accounting system in the finance ministry; increasing the legal requirements for financial reporting; ensuring the independence of the audit organization; and focusing on a value for money audits. In contrast, micro-level accountability results from two basic factors. The first refers to the willingness and ability of the public to an exit, meaning to consider other options when dissatisfied with a public service (Rupesinghe, 2016). Exit is greatly influenced by the degree to which the public has access to alternative suppliers of a given public service. Policies and mechanisms that promote greater competition like deregulation, contracting out of services to multiple private providers and public-private or public-public competition enhances exit. Citing Baumol and Lee (1991), the World Bank (1992) noted that contestability is crucial in creating a competitive environment. That is, when incumbents are made to bid for contracts along with outside competitors or when regulations favor new entrants, then incumbents are more conscious of turning in a good performance. The second aspect of micro-level accountability refers to the willingness and ability of the public to exert pressure on providers to perform well. Voice depends on the degree to which the public can influence the quality and quantity of a service through some form of articulation of preferences. A survey of beneficiaries' satisfaction with the amount of services provided is one way of providing "voice mechanisms." So are procedures for making complaints and institutions like the ombudsman. Participation of non-government organizations or private sector representatives in decision-making or regulatory bodies is still another way of promoting voice. The choice between exit and voice mechanisms should be guided by the factors which foster each of these options. The potential for exit depends on the presence of economies of scale (monopoly, e.g., the telecommunications industry used to consist of only one big industry player; so with the local airline industry), legal barriers to entry and spatial barriers to exit (e.g., remoteness of a village so that it is efficiently served by only one school or clinic). In contrast, the potential for voice is influenced by legal, institutional and informational barriers facing the public, the public=s level of income and education, and non-differentiability of the public service. For example, the absence of freedom of association, of participation and of expression certainly hampers the exercise of voice. So does lack of information. Also, low education levels constrain the publics ability to evaluate options and participate in public debates. Paul (1991) posits the following propositions in evaluating the menu of exit/voice options. First, when the public service operates as a local monopoly due to spatial barriers and when the public is characterized by low incomes and legal, institutional and informational barriers, improved accountability is better achieved through the use of voice. Under these conditions, the use of voice is likely to be stimulated by the intervention of agents outside of the local community (e.g., NGOs). Second, when the public service is characterized by large economies of scale and/or legal barriers to entry, when service differentiation is difficult and when the public is not constrained by low incomes and limited information, voice will tend to be used to induce greater accountability. The use of voice under these conditions is likely to be initiated by the public and not through external agents. Third, when public service can be differentiated, when it is not constrained by economies of scale and the public faces income, informational and institutional barriers, improved accountability is achieved through the use of exit. The World Bank (1992) also asserts that micro-level accountability reinforces macro-level accountability. On the other hand, Rupesinghe (2016) makes a stronger statement in noting that overall public accountability is sustainable only if macro-level accountability is reinforced by microlevel accountability but that competition and/or participation cannot substitute for good financial and economic accountability. Lander-Mills and Serageldin (1992) adds a third dimension to public accountability: political accountability. In their view, political accountability is enhanced by the presence of a system of popular choice which makes governments responsive to popular demand. Transparency and Information. Transparency implies the provision of relevant and reliable information to all. The private sector needs accurate and timely information about the economy and government policies for effective decision making. Transparency in decision making and implementation reduces uncertainty and can curb corruption among public officials. It complements and reinforces accountability (by enhancing efficient use of resources and by promoting participation) as well as predictability (by lowering uncertainty and transactions costs). Predictability, Presence of Legal Framework. Predictability refers to the fair and consistent application of laws, regulations and policies. This is important in creating a stable economic environment that allows prospective investors to assess opportunities and risks, to transact business with one another and to have a reasonable assurance or recourse against arbitrary interference (World Bank 1992). Predictability has five critical elements: "(1) there is a set of rules known in advance; (2) the rules are actually in force; (3) there are mechanisms assuring application of the rules; (4) conflicts are resolved through binding decisions of an independent judicial body; (5) there are procedures for amending the rules when they no longer serve their purpose." Efficiency of public sector. A capable public sector is one which collects its revenues efficiently, and one which plans, programs, and budgets its expenditures soundly. Social development. Good governance is one which promotes the health and well-being of its citizenry in a manner that is equitable. Sound economic management. For Huther and Shah (1998), sound economic management may be observed through the government=s outward orientation, central banks independence, and the debt-to-GDP ratio. Along the same lines, Osborne and Gaebler (1992) enumerate the characteristics of good governments -- decentralized, catalytic, community-owned, competitive, mission-driven, results oriented, customer-driven, enterprising, anticipatory and market-oriented. These are the same qualities that characterize the best-run companies or corporations. In the midst of serious social problems and swift global transformations, the authors espouse a highly decentralized, non-traditional form of governance to maximize productivity and effectiveness. Good governance based on these principles would mean a shift from traditional to new roles and structures. Catalytic and community-owned government. Local chief executives now assume the role of facilitating problem solving by stimulating the community into action. They are no longer confined to the tasks of collecting taxes and delivering services. They are also involved in defining community problems and mobilizing scarce public and private resources to achieve community aspirations. A catalytic local government assumes more "steering" functions (as opposed to "rowing") by "leading society, convincing its various interest groups to embrace common goals and strategies." As such, the focus of a catalytic government ( or one that acts as a change agent) shifts from "doing" things (from delivering services) to making more policy decisions and putting more social and economic institutions into motion. It is also one that ensures that other institutions are delivering services (in lieu of hiring more public employees to do the job). Catalytic local governments may contract out some services but privatization is just one of the answers. It is not the only answer. Community services and programs offered by local governments should be designed such that the clients are empowered and become less dependent on government for their needs. Ownership of programs by the community should be facilitated by local officials through the self-help process. Non-governmental organizations and people's organizations should be tapped to assist in promoting self-help and in formulating and implementing development projects. Competitive, enterprising, anticipatory, results-oriented governance. Local governments, as further illustrated by Rupesinghe (2016), should take a competitive stance to achieve greater efficiency. They should promote competition among service providers to keep costs down and to induce excellence for greater customer satisfaction. Local governments could enhance competition by encouraging private firms to provide goods and services that were previously provided by the public sector either by load shedding (with the government consciously withdrawing from public provision), procurement or contracting.

CHAPTER 3: RESEARCH METHODOLOGY 3.0 Introduction

The section highlights the methods to be used in achieving the research purposes on socio-economic effects of good governance on the economy.

3.1 Research Design

The research plans to study the aspects relating to good governance and the effect it has on the growth of a nation. The research shall examine the contributing aspects to the growth of nations beginning with the case of Africa while narrowing down to the case of Kenya that is used as a case study. The study shall stretch to the contributions made by the proper governance that has seen the development of constituencies, wards, and lately the contribution by the county government that was deliberated from prospects of good governance. The comparison shall be made alongside other African countries and their efforts towards good governance.

The research seeks to explore two distinct approaches through the qualitative and the quantitative means towards a comprehensive research process. The quantitative approach shall be essential in data collection that requires bulk information from the government and other governance related organizations such as Transparency International. The qualitative method shall be used in gathering and compiling information obtained from interviews and questionnaires from the respondents (Creswell & Creswell, 2017).

3.2 Population and Sampling

Kenya as large has experience in governance starting from the colonial to the post-colonial era, with its constitution being a guiding factor towards better governance. The research shall utilize a select number of 10 firms including government institutions where the information shall be sought. The primary source of the data shall come from respondents sought from the organizations, random citizens, and professionals in the field of governance and economy. The provincial and county offices shall be instrumental in the delivery of primary information. The information shall be sampled randomly to increase the chances of truth and dependability of the information obtained. In each location or source, a sample of 10 shall be used with a total target of 60 respondents expected. At the same time, the use of stratified sampling shall be explored to exercise fairness while avoiding biased information coming from a sector geared to promoting government policies on economic development.

3.3 Data Collection

Data collection involves gathering of information regarding a specific topic under research for study purposes. Data collection is the process of gathering and measuring information on variables of interest, in an established systematic fashion that enables one to answer stated research questions, test hypotheses, and evaluate outcomes.Data collection process must be done succinctly to increase dependency and relevancy of information that is essential not only for governance students but also for the government in measuring their developmental milestones. All these can be achieved by conducting the process in consideration of laid down guidelines in proper research practices that eliminate bias.

Regardless of the field of study or preference for defining data (quantitative, qualitative), accurate data collection is essential to maintaining the integrity of research. Both the selection of appropriate data collection instruments (existing, modified, or newly developed) and clearly delineated instructions for their correct use reduce the likelihood of errors occurring.

Consequences from improperly collected data include

  • inability to answer research questions accurately

  • inability to repeat and validate the study

  • distorted findings resulting in wasted resources

  • misleading other researchers to pursue fruitless avenues of investigation

  • compromising decisions for public policy

  • causing harm to human participants and animal subjects

The data collection process shall be done through interviews and questionnaires. First, the study shall use knowledgeable people in managing the research process equipped with the right tool towards a reliable outcome. The use of recorders, storage devices, analysis software, and scanners shall be used in keeping the information safe while reducing multiple handling of the information. At the same time, the items shall reduce the process of compiling the results while preserving the information for future use.

The questionnaires and interview scripts shall be prepared in advance and consideration placed on gender sensitive issues to increase participation while remaining responsible for the items stated therein. Guided questions shall be used as lead questions that will not only make the process easier but comprehensible to the respondents. After the data collection, the information shall be transcribed and stored confidentially to prevent interference and preserving ethical guidelines to the respondents.

In validating the information obtained, secondary data shall be used in providing further explanation and illustration of the level of governance experienced in Kenya. The use of books, peer reviewed articles, documentaries, and government papers shall occur in providing a lead to the study discussions and results.

Quality Control
While quality control activities (detection/monitoring and action) occur during and after data collection, the details should be carefully documented in the procedure’s manual. A clearly defined communication structure is a necessary pre-condition for establishing monitoring systems. There should not be any uncertainty about the flow of information between principal investigators and staff members following the detection of errors in data collection. A poorly developed communication structure encourages lax monitoring and limits opportunities for detecting errors.

Detection or monitoring can take the form of direct staff observation during site visits, conference calls, or regular and frequent reviews of data reports to identify inconsistencies, extreme values or invalid codes. While site visits may not be appropriate for all disciplines, failure to regularly audit records, whether quantitative or quantitative, will make it difficult for investigators to verify that data collection is proceeding according to procedures established in the manual. In addition, if the structure of communication is not clearly delineated in the procedures manual, transmission of any change in procedures to staff members can be compromised

Quality control also identifies the required responses, or ‘actions’ necessary to correct faulty data collection practices and also minimize future occurrences. These actions are less likely to occur if data collection procedures are vaguely written and the necessary steps to minimize recurrence are not implemented through feedback and education (Knatterud, et al, 1998)

3.4 Data Analysis

Compilation of data involves an assessment on the information retrieved from the study where it is classified to reflect directional responses on study issue. Data analysis is defined as a process of cleaning, transforming, and modeling data to discover useful information for business decision-making. The purpose of Data Analysis is to extract useful information from data and taking the decision based upon the data analysis.

Whenever we take any decision in our day-to-day life is by thinking about what happened last time or what will happen by choosing that particular decision. This is nothing but analyzing our past or future and making decisions based on it. For that, we gather memories of our past or dreams of our future. So that is nothing but data analysis. Now same thing analyst does for business purposes, is called Data Analysis.

A summary from the respondents shall be accessed where the responses shall be placed on one end to find a comparative pattern on the issue of governance. The positives and negative responses shall be analyzed in numbers to determine the extent to which the governance measures have changed the nation.

The analysis shall be used to indicate the relevance of the information collected on the field with that reported from the secondary sources. In the process of analysis, both inductive and deductive methods shall be utilized where induction shall be important in assessing the pattern of governance while the deduction shall come in handy in comparing the theories and their relation to the case happening in the economy of the nation (Quinlan, Babin, Carr, & Griffin, 2019).

3.5 Research Quality

Quality in research remains essential in guaranteeing a successful and trustworthy research process. Moreover, superior research quality makes study information reliable thus instilling trust in the process. The information obtained shall be stored well for evidence with the recordings and questionnaires remaining within reach of persons in the research (Quinlan, Babin, Carr & Griffin, 2019). The measure explored shall increase credibility while reducing chances on information tampering. The methods used in the research remain of high quality based on the provable written responses that can be confirmed and reviewed by other parties in the research. The information obtained shall be dependable based on the stratified sampling which shall consider gender to receive an all-round view from the respondents.

3.6 Ethical Considerations

Ethics is defined as a set of morals to be followed when no one is being observed or lack thereof. Ethics tend to protect the researcher and the respondents in avoiding to damage the parties in a research process. Respect to respondents is paramount as they are conducting the research in terms of responses based on voluntary terms and with the trust that the documents will not be used against them.

he consideration of ethics in research, and in general business for that matter, is of growing importance. It is, therefore, critical that you understand the basics of ethical research and how this might affect your research project. This is especially important if your research involves interaction with businesses or members of the general community who serve as participants (i.e., respondents) in your research. There are a range of interactions in your research that might occur, including in-depth interviews, focus groups, surveys, or even observing people’s behavior. Though all researchers (student, professional, or academic) are well intentioned, there is the possibility that interaction with participants may inadvertently harm them in some unintended way. This could include • Psychological harm—for example, researching the use of nudity in advertising may show participants images that offend them. • Financial harm—researching unethical behavior within a given firm may provide management with information on individual employees that results in an individual getting fired, or undertaking industrybased research may inadvertently share sensitive information with a firm’s competitors, resulting in financial harm to the organization. • Social harm—researching how lifestyle affects consumption may unintentionally disclose a person’s sexual orientation when that person wanted to keep this confidential. It is your responsibility to consider whether any type of harm could occur when you plan your research and to ensure that mechanisms are instituted to remove it. It is, therefore, essential that you carefully evaluate the potential for harm to arise and ensure that you (a) behave according to appropriate ethical standards; (b) consider how your research might negatively affect participants; and (c) protect yourself, your supervisors/teachers, and your institution from being placed in situations in which individuals could make claims of inappropriate behavior, resulting in public criticism or even your being sued.

The research shall guarantee the privacy of the respondents that shall be foretold to them. The right to privacy shall be done through communication and omission of names in the response materials as well as conceal of names during interviews. In enhancing confidence, a consent form from the institution of study shall be presented to the respondents where their participation shall be fully on voluntary grounds (Pietilä, Nurmi, Halkoaho & Kyngäs, 2020). The consent form shall entail the rights of the respondents that shall be followed to the latter in safeguarding their interests while achieving study objectives.

At the same time, the data collection methods shall ensure no information of sensitive nature shall be present in the interview and questionnaire sheet. Lastly, the respondents shall be made aware of the use of the information which shall remain purely for educational purposes. An assurance that the information shall not leak to the public and be used for ill-motives shall be guaranteed. According to Pietilä, Nurmi, Halkoaho & Kyngäs (2020), these shall be important in making the process seamless while getting the most out of the respondents.

Chapter 4: DATA ANALYSIS, INTERPRETATION, AND PRESENTATION 4.0 Introduction

The chapter examines data presented, interpretation of the issues involved in coming up with the final presentation of research information. The data in the case was collected from the regional administration offices, county government, and Transparency International where issues of governance were the key focus therein.

4.1 Questionnaire Response

The research had a total of 40 people with half being citizens visiting the offices and the rest being professionals in the field of economy and governance. Out of 40, a total of 32 responded in the exercise which demonstrated a good turn-out. The 8 cited lack of interest, lack of time, and unsure nature on the information as the core reason for decline. Therefore, the response level indicates a high and satiable number critical to responding to the study objectives.

4.2 Questionnaire Response Rate

Respondents

Sample size

Response

%

National administration

20

15

75

County government

10

8

80

Transparency International

10

9

90

TOTAL

40

32

4.3 Study Demography

The study spread its target individual across gender, education level, and age to include the image of the whole nation’s representation. 15 out of 40 were women whose number in the places visited for research remained low. The education level of the respondents was high school and above with the highest being a PHD. The ages were spread from 18 years onwards to 65 years. Men became the majority with most of them remaining open in their views compared to that of women.

4.4 Educational Level

The study explored high school and above in obtaining a proper response on the issues of national importance. 10 were high school qualified, 15 diplomas, 5 masters, and 9 were degree holders with 1 being a PHD holder. The spread was essential in coming up with a diverse response based on expectations in answering to the study questions. The education level was an important factor in understanding the comprehension of governance across the population.

Level of Education

No.

Percentage

KCSE

10

25%

DIPLOMA

15

37.5%

UNDERGRADUATE

12.5%

MASTERS

22.5%

PHD

2.5%

TOTAL

40

100%

4.5 Positive Indication of governance

The section presents governance question responses on the extent to which the government has improved its structures towards increasing socio-economic development. 15 out of 32 indicated a high level of governance that has steered the growth presently. The section explained of the aggression in the past 10 decades where the nation has achieved a lot of issues compared to the last 5 decades that were characterized by dictatorial regimes where little development could spark up. The moderate level seems to validate the presence of development occasioned by good governance though relate the numbers as low compared to the case of nations that were at par with Kenya in the 90s such as Singapore. The lower level reports of little socio-economic effects attached to good governance thereby indicating a problem in the governance structure where the interests of the middle and lower level individuals are hardly achieved.

Governance indication (has governance improved?)

No.

Percentage

HIGH

15

46%

MODERATE

10

32%

LOW

22%

TOTAL

32

100%

4.6 Benefits of Proper Governance

The section entails response on a scale of 1-10 on how the people have experienced or agree to the benefits of good governance changing the economic standards of a nation. Most of the respondents indicated an improvement in the governance standards in the last two decades that has steered economic growth.

In overall, there is an indication that the latest developments resulting from good governance have steered the economy of the nation. Vastly, respondents agreed that the creation of county governments was a step in the right direction that not only opened up the rural areas but also provided job opportunities and investments that had an effect on the economic status of the nation. At the same time, the respondents pointed to the new constitution and the competitive election as key facilitators to good leadership that caters for the provisions in the constitution. Compared to the case prior to the end of Moi era and multiparty, development was only featured in some regions with those in opposition remaining in poverty and lack of infrastructural development. The people in the villages benefit from the improved health standards, environmental considerations, and a growth in the economic standard of the nation.

Benefits

Scale (1-10)

Percentage

KCSE

70

DIPLOMA

80

UNDERGRADUATE

80

MASTERS

70

PHD

60

However, an improvement was pointed out by the Transparency International on the use of loans and other grants in steering the economy. Cases of corruption and misappropriation of funds were cited as derailing factors to achievement of socio-economic benefits gains from good governance. The organization was able to highlight the cases of infrastructural projects that have failed to yield benefits despite the large sums of money invested. The results indicate cases of poor governance and a deteriorating economy which struggles to pay off its loans towards realizing change in the socio-economic dimensions. The constant political interference on the economy has been pointed out as a detrimental factor that affects the governance structure of the nation based on the slower pace of economic growth in times of campaigns and electioneering periods. Despite the demerit observed, the nation seems to be on the right track with a few improvements on policies to curb corruption being put in place.












CHAPTER 5: SUMMARY, CONCLUSION AND RECOMMENDATIONS 5.0 Introduction

The chapter provides the summary of the study discussions, conclusion, and recommendations towards god governance. The study aimed to observe the issue of governance, its benefits and the gaps existing in realization of long-term benefits of good governance. All these have been achieved from the research both in the primary sources and the secondary sources that seem to agree on most of the provisions.

On objective one, the aspect of governance remains close to the case of Kenya, which despite experiencing frequent changes in the political field continues to thrive in its economic developments. The economy of Kenya has strengthened despite the current shakes caused by global shifts and the Covid-19 pandemic. On objective two, the benefits can be seen in the improved living standards of the people and several developments in sectors of the economy. The manufacturing, processing, and hospitality industries have grown based on the governance policies that attract investors to the nation. All these are pointers to the good governance that is described to have picked up since 2003 as the new regime took power. The constant and increased importation of goods and investment in the health sector has vastly improved the lives of people.

The development seen between the years 2004-2020 records an increase in the economic stature of the nation; a fact related to the change of governance structures and policies. Moreover, the coming of the county governments has injected life in the rural areas; some of which experienced neglect as the national government had a greater focus in the cities and towns. The present reality of good roads, improved healthcare, increased investment, employment opportunities, and free education has been an indicator to gains in the socio-economic dimensions.

The third objective remains present in the case of Kenya; which acts as an impending factor to the full realization of socio-economic development. Proper leadership is a requisite factor to the development of an economy, more so in the developing nations. In this respect, the fourth objective seeks to be achieved through the recommendations on better strategies to good governance.

Conclusion

Countries around the world differ in the economic levels depending on the type of input placed from its leaders. The input revolves around the governance structures that guide the process of development. The best governance is achieved through consideration of people, processes, purpose, and performance in achieving end goals. Kenya is set to achieve more with the proactive and dynamic governance it implores towards growing its economy. There is a need for the gaps in governance to be bridged through adoption of the below recommendations in increasing transparency, communication, and use of technology in cost-cutting while boosting the pace of development.




Recommendations

Implementation- The best practice in realizing change relates to a good implementation phase that ensures proper utilization of resources in achieving target goals. The government needs to accelerate the rate of delivery in stabilizing the economy with a world class implementation module that ensures a project’s success.

Technology – the use of technology is critical to the development of governance as it increases the efficiency levels. The new system increases efficiencies by cutting down costs in information exchange, monitoring and evaluation, and in boosting transparency. Online applications for government services enhance service delivery while increasing taxes to the government which in turn builds the economy.

Communication – implementing change in the economy calls for effective and clear communication to optimize resources while creating trust to the public. A government that remains open and transparent increases its chances of developing as public participation helps in ownership of projects. Moreover, it leads to better cooperation and collaboration among the two parties which drives success in governance.

Monitoring and Evaluation

Monitoring of government projects is an essential tool towards aligning plans to goals. Monitoring allows project managers to continuously monitor and align structures to fit the desired ends which result in public good. A strong monitoring system needs to be placed on government policies and projects to ensure they yield benefits to the public rather than to a few individuals. The strategy is important in barring corruption and stalling of government projects that have consumed public resources. Evaluation comes in the last stage to determine whether the objectives have been met or not and propose for changes to enhance success.

Equitability

The development of a nation occurs with the allocation of resources equally which allows sections of the nation to develop uniformly. A selective allocation of resources as in the previous regime limited the growth of other zones. The government has tried to overcome the challenge through county government formation policies but needs to do more to inject funds to the county government towards the posterity of the nation. Adopt integrity structures that encourage zero tolerance on corrupt activities where only people with impeccable integrity are picked for such services.


References

Atkinson, A. B., & Bourguignon, F. (Eds.). (2014). Handbook of income distribution (Vol. 2). Elsevier.

Beresford, P., & Croft, S. (2016). Citizen involvement: A practical guide for change. Macmillan International Higher Education.

Beunen, R., Van Assche, K., & Duineveld, M. (2016). Evolutionary governance theory. Springer International Pu.

Brinkerhoff, D. W., & Wetterberg, A. (2016). Gauging the effects of social accountability on services, governance, and citizen empowerment. Public Administration Review76(2), 274-286.

Creswell, J. W., & Creswell, J. D. (2017). Research design: Qualitative, quantitative, and mixed methods approaches. Sage publications.

Fan, G. H., & Zietsma, C. (2017). Constructing a shared governance logic: The role of emotions in enabling dually embedded agency. Academy of Management Journal60(6), 2321-2351.

Fayissa, B., & Nsiah, C. (2013). The impact of governance on economic growth in Africa. The Journal of Developing Areas, 91-108.

Flew, T., Martin, F., & Suzor, N. (2019). Internet regulation as media policy: Rethinking the question of digital communication platform governance. Journal of Digital Media & Policy10(1), 33-50.

He, X., Eden, L., & Hitt, M. A. (2016). Shared governance: Institutional investors as a counterbalance to the state in state owned multinationals. Journal of International Management22(2), 115-130.

Lubell, M., Mewhirter, J., Berardo, R., & Scholz, J. (2019). The Origins of Conflict in Polycentric Governance Systems.

Mira, R., & Hammadache, A. (2017). Relationship Between Good Governance and Economic Growth. A Contribution to the Institutional Debate About State Failure in Developing Countries. A Contribution to the Institutional Debate About State Failure in Developing Countries.(April 1, 2017). CEPN Centre d’économie de l’Université Paris Nord CNRS UMR, (7234).

Moore, M. (2004). Revenues, state formation, and the quality of governance in developing countries. International Political Science Review25(3), 297-319.

Moskowitz, K. (2017). Sweating to Help Themselves: Self-Help and the Contradictions of Citizenship and Development in Decolonizing Kenya. International Journal of African Historical Studies50(1), 35-58.

Owoye, O., & Onafowora, O. A. (2017). 3 Understanding Africa’s governance structures and its economic growth performance. Democratizing Public Governance in Developing Nations: With Special Reference to Africa, 1.

Pietilä, A. M., Nurmi, S. M., Halkoaho, A., & Kyngäs, H. (2020). Qualitative Research: Ethical Considerations. In The Application of Content Analysis in Nursing Science Research (pp. 49-69). Springer, Cham.

Pollitt, C., & Bouckaert, G. (2017). Public management reform: A comparative analysis-into the age of austerity. Oxford University Press.

Quinlan, C., Babin, B., Carr, J., & Griffin, M. (2019). Business research methods. South Western Cengage.

Ríos, A. M., Benito, B., & Bastida, F. (2017). Factors explaining public participation in the central government budget process. Australian Journal of Public Administration76(1), 48-64.

Rupesinghe, K. (Ed.). (2016). Internal conflict and governance. Springer.

Schwartz, R. (2017). Public Management Theory, Evaluation, and Evidence-Based Policy. In Mind the Gap (pp. 131-148). Routledge.

Vlachokyriakos, V., Crivellaro, C., Le Dantec, C. A., Gordon, E., Wright, P., & Olivier, P. (2016, May). Digital civics: Citizen empowerment with and through technology. In Proceedings of the 2016 CHI conference extended abstracts on human factors in computing systems (pp. 1096-1099).

Vlachokyriakos, V., Crivellaro, C., Le Dantec, C. A., Gordon, E., Wright, P., & Olivier, P. (2016, May). Digital civics: Citizen empowerment with and through technology. In Proceedings of the 2016 CHI conference extended abstracts on human factors in computing systems (pp. 1096-1099).

APPENDIX I: QUESTIONNAIRE

Dear Participant,

My name is Mathieu Niyongabo. I am a student in Northwestern Christian University, pursuing Doctorate (PhD) in Leadership administration and management. I am conducting a study to explore on the effects good governance on the socio-economic sector with Kenya serving as a case study. I kindly request you to fill this questionnaire which will aid the research in rates of corruption and I finding solutions or recommendations to better service. Your responses will be used for academic purposes only and will be treated with confidentiality and your name shall not be mentioned in any part of this research. Feel free to engage and a make a difference in good governance.

Section A. Background Information

  1. What is your sex?

    1. M


      ale
    2. F


      emale

  1. What is your highest level of education?

    1. S


      econdary school/ below
    2. D


      iploma level
    3. U


      niversity level


  1. What is your age?

    1. 1


      8 – 30 years
    2. 3


      1 – 45 years
    3. 4


      6 years and above


  1. What is your occupation status?

    1. E


      mployed
    2. S


      elf employed
    3. U


      nemployed


  1. How long have you had interest in governance issues?

    1. 1


      – 5 years
    2. 6


      – 10 years
    3. M


      ore than 10 years



Section B: Effect of good governance on development

To what extent does good governance provide room for development? using the scale of 1 – 5

(1 – strongly disagree; 2 - Disagree; 3 Moderate; 4 – Agree; 5 – Strongly agree).

Activity

1

2

3

4

5

  1. Good governance leads to open opportunities

  1. Good governance leads to proper social setup

  1. Does your government give you proper governance?

  1. Have you been affected by poor governance?


Thank you for taking part in this study


Section C: Effect of good governance (personal experience)

To what extent does good governance affect your personal social and economic growth? using the scale of 1 – 5 (1 – strongly disagree; 2 - Disagree; 3 Moderate; 4 – Agree; 5 – Strongly agree).


Activity

1

2

3

4

5

  1. Do you strain in accessing services due to poor governance?

  1. Do you like the way you country is governed?

  1. Have you ever been a leader at some point?

  1. Do you think the present governance is okay?

  1. Have you ever reported cases on poor governance?


Thank you for taking part in this study


Section D: Impact of good governance on socio-economic development

using the scale of 1 – 5 (1 – strongly disagree; 2 - Disagree; 3 Moderate; 4 – Agree; 5 – Strongly agree).



Activity

1

2

3

4

5

  1. Has Kenya developed in the past decade due to good governance?

  1. Have you benefited from the latest governance measures?

  1. Do you feel there are gaps in the present governance that need to be strengthened?


Thank you for taking part in this study

105