PA Assg. #13–Please see attached instructions. Thank you.

An Integrative Framework for Collaborative Governance Author(s): Kirk Emerson, Tina Nabatchi and Stephen Balogh Source: Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory: J-PART , January 2012 , Vol. 22, No. 1 (January 2012), pp. 1-29 Published by: Oxford University Press on behalf of the Public Management Research Association Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/41342607 JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at https://about.jstor.org/terms and Oxford University Press are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory: J-PART This content downloaded from 128.6.45.205 on Thu, 26 Aug 2021 02:44:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms ARTICLES JPART 22:1-29 An Integrative Framework for Collaborative Governance Kirk Emerson * Tina Na batch P, Stephen Ba log h* *The University of Arizona; 'Syracuse University; * State University of New York ABSTRACT Collaborative governance draws from diverse realms of practice and research in public administration. This article synthesizes and extends a suite of conceptual frameworks, research findings, and practice-based knowledge into an integrative framework for collaborative governance. The framework specifies a set of nested dimensions that encompass a larger system context, a collaborative governance regime, and its internal collaborative dynamics and actions that can generate impacts and adaptations across the systems. The framework provides a broad conceptual map for situating and exploring components of cross-boundary governance systems that range from policy or program- based intergovernmental cooperation to place-based regional collaboration with nongovernmental stakeholders to public-private partnerships. The framework integrates knowledge about individual incentives and barriers to collection action, collaborative social learning and conflict resolution processes, and institutional arrangements for cross-boundary collaboration. It is presented as a general framework that might be applied to analyses at different scales, in different policy arenas, and varying levels of complexity. The article also offers 10 propositions about the dynamic interactions among components within the framework and concludes with a discussion about the implications of the framework for theory, research, evaluation, and practice. INTRODUCTION Collaborative governance has become a common term in the public administration literature, yet its definition remains amorphous and its use inconsistent. Moreover, the var- iation in the scope and scale of perspectives on collaborative governance restricts the ability of researchers to further develop and test theory. This article addresses some of the The authors would like to express sincere gratitude for the detailed comments and suggestions received from the anonymous reviewers. The quality of their reviews was remarkable and significantly improved the quality of this work. Special thanks to Olivier Barreteau, Charles Curtin, Neda Farahbakhshazad, Peter Murchie, and Marilyn Tenbrink for their formative comments on the framework and to Christine Carlson, Andrea Gerlak, and Rosemary O'Leary for their initial review of this article. We are also indebted to those who provided feedback on earlier presentations of the framework at the Udall Center for Studies in Public Policy at The University of Arizona and at the Collaborative Governance and Climate Change Conference in June 2009 sponsored by the Association for Conflict Resolution's Environment and Public Policy Section. Address correspondence to the author at [email protected]. doi:10.1093/jopart/mur01 1 Advance Access publication on May 2, 201 1 ©The Author 2011. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of the Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory, Inc. All rights reserved. For permissions, please e-mail: [email protected] This content downloaded from 128.6.45.205 on Thu, 26 Aug 2021 02:44:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 2 Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory conceptual limitations associated with the study of collaborative governance. It synthesizes and extends a suite of conceptual frameworks, research findings, and practice-based- knowledge into an integrative framework for researching, practicing, and evaluating collaborative governance. The framework for collaborative governance is integrative in several ways. First, our definition of collaborative governance is broader than what is commonly seen in the literature, and our framework draws on and applies knowledge and concepts from a wide range of fields (such as public administration, conflict resolution, and environmental management among othersyf W R F R O O D E R U D W L Y H J R Y H U Q D Q F H 7 K L V P D N H V W K H I U D P H Z R U k potentially relevant to scholars and practitioners working in several applications and settings, such as collaborative public management, multipartner governance, joined-up or network government, hybrid sectoral arrangements, co-management regimes, participatory governance, and civic engagement, all of which share common characteristics with collaborative governance writ large. Second, the framework integrates numerous components of collaborative governance - from system context and external drivers through collaborative dynamics to actions, impacts, and adaptation. This enables scholars to study a collaborative governance regime (CGRyf D V D Z K R O H R U W R I R F X V R Q L W V Y D U L R X s components and/or elements, while facilitating interdisciplinary research on complex, multilevel systems. Finally, it organizes several variables into a multilevel framework, enabling further analysis of the internal dynamics and causal pathways of collaborative governance and its performance. Together, these attributes can allow for the broad application of the integrative framework across sectors, settings, processes, issues, and time. In this article, we first define collaborative governance and explore its scope and origins in the public administration and related literatures. We then present the framework for collaborative governance along with 10 propositions to guide future inquiry and theory building. We conclude with a discussion about the implications of the framework for public administration theory, research, and practice. DEFINING COLLABORATIVE GOVERNANCE: SCOPE AND ORIGINS As a general term, "governance" refers to the act of governing, be it in the public and/or private sector. Within the context of collective action, Ostrom (1990yf F R Q V L G H U V J R Y H U Q D Q F e as a dimension of jointly determined norms and rules designed to regulate individual and group behavior. O'Leary, Bingham, and Gerard (2006, 7yf G H I L Q H J R Y H U Q D Q F H D V W K H P H D Q s to steer the process that influences decisions and actions within the private, public, and civic sectors." More specifically, governance is "a set of coordinating and monitoring activities" that enables the survival of the collaborative partnership or institution (Bryson, Crosby, and Stone 2006yf . We define collaborative governance broadly as the processes and structures of public policy decision making and management that engage people constructively across the boundaries of public agencies, levels of government , and/or the public , private and civic spheres in order to carry out a public purpose that could not otherwise be accomplished. This definition allows collaborative governance to be used as a broader analytic construct in public administration and enables distinctions among different applications, classes, and scales. It responds, in part, to the observation by Ansell and Gash (2008, 544yf W K D W V F K R O D U s This content downloaded from 128.6.45.205 on Thu, 26 Aug 2021 02:44:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Emerson et al. Integrative Framework for Collaborative Governance have been focusing more "on the species rather than the genus" of collaborative governance. Moreover, our definition of collaborative governance captures a fuller range of emergent forms of cross-boundary governance, extending beyond the conventional focus on the public manager or the formal public sector. Thus, it is broader than the definition proposed by Ansell and Gash (2008, 544yf $ J R Y H U Q L Q J D U U D Q J H P H Q W Z K H U H R Q H R U P R U e public agencies directly engage non-state stakeholders in a collective decision-making- process that is formal, consensus-oriented, and deliberative and that aims to make or implement public policy or manage public programs or assets." Unlike the Ansell and Gash definition, our definition does not limit collaborative governance to only formal, state-initiated arrangements, and to engagement between government and nongovernmen- tal stakeholders. For example, our definition encompasses "multipartner governance," which can include partnerships among the state, the private sector, civil society, and the community, as well as joined-up government and hybrid arrangements such as public-private and private-social partnerships and co-management regimes (Agrawal and Lemos 2007yf , W D O V R L Q F O X G H V W K H P \ U L D G R I F R P P X Q L W \ E D V H G F R O O D E R U D W L Y H V L Q Y R O Y H d in collective resource management (that often invite the participation of public agenciesyf , as well as intergovernmental collaborative structures such as interstate river basin com- missions governed by state and federal government representatives, and federal inter- agency collaboration among on public health policy or climate change science, among other types of collaborative arrangements initiated in the private or civic sectors (Emerson and Murchie 2010yf ) L Q D O O \ L W F D Q D O V R E H D S S O L H G W R R U X V H G W R L Q I R U P S D U W L F L S D W R U y governance and civic engagement, although we recognize that the extent of involvement by citizens and the public in collaborative governance can vary considerably. Recently, several scholars have traced the multifaceted provenance of collaborative governance (Ansell and Gash 2008; Bingham and O'Leary 2008; Cooper, Bryer, and Meek 2006; Fung 2006; Sirianni 2009yf W K X V R Q O \ D E U L H I U H Y L H Z R I V R P H R I L W V P D M R r connections to public administration is presented here. Specifically, we identify some of its origins in theory, its connection to broader notions of public administration and democracy, and its application to various management practices and in different manage- ment settings. In terms of theory, several scholars connect the concept of collaborative governance with the study of intergovernmental cooperation in the 1 960s (Agranoff and McGuire 2003 ; Elazar 1962, 1984yf Z K H U H D V R W K H U V W U D F H L W V U R R W V E D F N W R W K H E L U W K R I $ P H U L F D Q I H G H U D O L V m itself - "the most enduring model of collaborative problem resolution" (McGuire 2006yf . Collaborative governance has also been connected to Bentley' s (1949yf J U R X S W K H R U \ D Q G W K e subsequent theoretical reaction and evolution from Olsen' s (1965yf / R J L F R I & R O O H F W L Y e Action , to the prisoner's dilemma and game theory (Axelrod 1984; Dawes 1973yf D Q d to the extensive common-pool resource literature (Ostrom 1990yf . Similarly, collaborative governance strikes at the heart of broader concepts of public ad- ministration and democracy. For many public administration scholars, collaborative governance is the new paradigm for governing in democratic systems (Frederickson 1991; Jun 2002; Kettl 2002yf ' H P R F U D F \ W K H R U L V W V D Q G U H V H D U F K H U V K D Y H O R Q J F R P P H Q W H G R Q W K e decline in American civic institutions, voting behavior, and social capital (Fishkin 1991; Nabatchi2010; Putnam 1995; Sirianni 2009; Skocpol2002yf 6 X F K R E V H U Y D W L R Q V K D Y H L Q V S L U H d new forms of public involvement and civic engagement, referred to by many as the 3This content downloaded from 128.6.45.205 on Thu, 26 Aug 2021 02:44:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory deliberative democracy movement (Fung and Wright 2001; Nabatchi 2010; Sirianni 2009; Torres 2003yf ' H O L E H U D W L Y H G H P R F U D F \ S U R P L V H V F L W L ] H Q V R S S R U W X Q L W L H V W R H [ H U F L V H Y R L F H D Q d a more responsive, citizen-centered government by embedding "governance systems and institutions with greater levels of transparency, accountability and legitimacy" (Henton, Melville, Amsler, and Kopell 2005, 5; see also Bryson, Crosby, and Stone 2006; Nabatchi 2010yf . Collaborative governance also has roots in management practices. At its core, Kettl (2006yf G H V F U L E H V W K H F R O O D E R U D W L R Q L P S H U D W L Y H D V F U R V V E R X Q G D U \ 0 F * X L U H \f points out that the importance of shared administration was recognized at the start of the literature on policy implementation (see also Pressman and Wildavsky 1973yf , Q W H U J R Y H U Q P H Q W D l relations and network theory helped give rise to studies about horizontal network management and collaborative public management (Agranoff and McGuire 2001; Kamensky and Burlin 2004; Wright 1988yf * D P H W K H R U \ S U R P X O J D W H G D W W H Q W L R Q W o interest-based negotiation and mutual gains bargaining (Fisher, Ury, and Patton 1991; Raiffa 1982yf D Q G L Q I R U P H G W K H S U D F W L F H R I D O W H U Q D W L Y H G L V S X W H U H V R O X W L R Q F R Q I O L F W P D Q D J H - ment, and consensus building in labor relations, personnel management, contracting, and environmental and public policy (Goldberg, Sanders, and Rogers 1992; O'Leary and Bingham 2003; Susskind, McKearnan, and Thomas-Larmer 1999yf . Within these streams of theory and research, collaborative governance has been applied and studied in several policy contexts. It has been used by law enforcement agencies (e.g., Nicholson-Crotty and O'Toole 2004yf W K H 9 H W H U D Q V + H D O W h Administration (e.g., Dudley and Raymer 2001yf D Q G W K H ' H S D U W P H Q W R I + R P H O D Q G 6 H F X U L W y (e.g., Jenkins 2006; Taylor 2006yf , W K D V E H H Q D S S O L H G W R F K L O G D Q G I D P L O \ V H U Y L F H G H O L Y H U y (e.g., Berry et al. 2008; Graddy and Chen 2006; Page 2003; Sowa 2008yf D Q G W R J R Y H U Q P H Q t contracting (e.g., Bloomfield 2006; Brown, Potoski, and Van Slyke 2007; Romzek and Johnston 2005yf & R O O D E R U D W L Y H J R Y H U Q D Q F H D S S U R D F K H V K D Y H E H H Q L Q V W U X P H Q W D O W R O R F D O H F R - nomic policy (e.g., Agranoff and McGuire 1998yf F U L V L V P D Q D J H P H Q W H J ) D U D ] D P D Q d 2007; Kettl 2006yf F R O O D E R U D W L R Q E H W Z H H Q H Q Y L U R Q P H Q W D O D J H Q F L H V D Q G V W D W H D Q G O R F D O S X E O L c health departments (e.g., Daley 2009yf D Q G R Q H Q Y L U R Q P H Q W D O L V V X H V V X F K D V W K H S U R W H F W L R n of open-spaces (e.g., Smith 2009yf Q D W X U D O U H V R X U F H V P D Q D J H P H Q W H J ' X U D Q W H W D O ; Koontz and Thomas 2006yf D Q G I R U H V W P D Q D J H P H Q W L Q E R W K W K H 8 Q L W H G 6 W D W H V H J 0 D Q U L Q g 2005yf D Q G , Q G L D H J ( E U D K L P . X P D U . D Q W D Q G $ P E X U J H \ \f. AN INTEGRATIVE FRAMEWORK FOR COLLABORATIVE GOVERNANCE In order to develop a useful framework for collaborative governance with which to better understand, develop, and test theory, as well as improve practice, we needed to explore and synthesize a broad array of literature. This included work in many different applied fields, such as public administration, planning, conflict management, and environmental gover- nance among others. We began with literature that speaks directly to collaborative gov- ernance, then moved to those literatures that are more tangentially related to collaborative governance, and finally to literatures that connect to particular concepts that we identified and/or developed in the integrative framework. Our goal was to look across various research lenses to see how they might inform collaborative governance, that is, to see how different research streams could illuminate the drivers, engagement processes, motivational attributes, and joint capacities that enable shared decision making, 4This content downloaded from 128.6.45.205 on Thu, 26 Aug 2021 02:44:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Emerson et al. Integrative Framework for Collaborative Governance management, implementation, and other activities across organizations, jurisdictions, and sectors. We also searched for relevant conceptual frameworks that were grounded in empirical studies. Chief among the frameworks we reviewed are those for: cross-sector collaboration (Bryson, Crosby, and Stone 2006yf F R O O D E R U D W L Y H S O D Q Q L Q J % H Q W U X S , Q Q V D Q G % R R K H r 1999; Selin and Chavez 1995yf F R O O D E R U D W L R Q S U R F H V V H V ' D Q L H O V D Q G : D O N H U 5 L Q g and Van de Ven 1994; Thomson and Perry 2006; Wood and Gray 1991yf Q H W Z R U k management (Koppenjan and Klijn 2004; Milward and Provan 2000yf F R O O D E R U D W L Y H S X E O L c management (Agranoff and McGuire 2001; Cooper, Bryer, and Meek 2006; Leach 2006yf , environmental governance and conflict resolution (Agrawal and Lemos 2007; Emerson et al. 2009yf D Q G F R O O D E R U D W L Y H J R Y H U Q D Q F H $ Q V H O O D Q G * D V K \f. In comparing these frameworks, we found expected overlap and considerable variation. The variations stem, in part, from the different research traditions, policy arenas, and scales in which these scholars work.1 Another common challenge we encountered with these frameworks is a lack of generalizability, that is, their inapplicability across different settings, sectors, geographic and temporal scales, policy arenas, and process mechanisms.2 Despite these variations, each of the above frameworks (and the research streams in which they are locatedyf K H O S H G L Q I R U P D Q G U H I L Q H R X U D S U L R U L D V V X P S W L R Q V D E R X W F D W H J R U L H V D Q d variables in the integrative framework and helped to identify important categories and variables that we had missed. Ostrom (2007yf Z D U Q V D E R X W W K H S H U L O V D V V R F L D W H G Z L W K F R Q V W U X F W L Q J I U D P H Z R U N V R I W K L s sort and the problems of creating "panaceas," models that are either overly simplistic or overly specified and burdened with long lists of variables and exacting conditions to meet and test. We approached this dilemma by identifying a relatively small number of dimensions within which components are posited to work together in a nonlinear, interactive fashion to produce actions, which lead to outcomes (actions and impactsyf D Q G L Q W X U Q D G D S W D W L R Q . Our integrative framework for collaborative governance is depicted in figure 1 as three nested dimensions, shown as boxes, representing the general system context, the collab- orative governance regime (CGRyf D Q G L W V F R O O D E R U D W L Y H G \ Q D P L F V D Q G D F W L R Q V 7 K H R X W - ermost box, depicted by solid lines, represents the surrounding system context or the host of political, legal, socioeconomic, environmental and other influences that affect and are af- fected by the CGR. This system context generates opportunities and constraints and influ- ences the dynamics of the collaboration at the outset and over time. From this system context emerge drivers , including leadership, consequential incentives, interdependence, and uncertainty, which help initiate and set the direction for a CGR. i For example, Selin and Chavez (1995yf I R F X V R Q H Q Y L U R Q P H Q W D O S O D Q Q L Q J D Q G P D Q D J H P H Q W J H Q H U D O O \ Z K H U H D s Bentrup (2001yf I R F X V H V V S H F L I L F D O O \ R Q Z D W H U V K H G S O D Q Q L Q J . R S S H Q M D Q D Q G . O L M Q \f study problem solving and decision making in networks, whereas Ring and Van de Ven (1994yf H [ D P L Q H E X V L Q H V V W U D Q V D F W L R Q V 0 R U H R Y H U W K e frameworks vary by the nature of the conceptual problem addressed. For example, Thomson and Perry (2006yf I R F X V R n the processes of interorganizational partnerships, whereas Cooper, Bryer and Meek (2006yf H [ D P L Q H G \ Q D P L F V R f engaging stakeholders and the public in community planning. 2 For example, the conflict resolution research often focuses on short time frames for reaching explicit agreements, thus missing the longer term implementation challenges or institutional dimensions (Emerson et al. 2009yf 7 K e intergovernmental and network management analyses tend to be focused on delivery of public services, often at local scales (Agranoff and McGuire 2001; Milward and Provan 2000yf $ V Q R W H G D E R Y H $ Q V H O O D Q G * D V K \f emphasize government-initiated processes with nongovernmental stakeholders. 5This content downloaded from 128.6.45.205 on Thu, 26 Aug 2021 02:44:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory Figure 1 The Integrative Framework for Collaborative Governance The concept of a CGR is a central feature in this framework. We use the term "regime" to encompass the particular mode of, or system for, public decision making in which cross-boundary collaboration represents the prevailing pattern of behavior and activity. Crosby and Bryson (2005, 51yf D O V R X V H W K L V W H U P L Q W K H L U Z R U N G U D Z L Q J R n Krasner's (1983, 2yf G H I L Q L W L R Q R I U H J L P H D V V H W V R I L P S O L F L W D Q G H [ S O L F L W S U L Q F L S O H V U X O H V , norms, and decision-making procedures around which actors' expectations converge in a given area." In this framework, the CGR is depicted by the middle box with the dashed lines and contains both the collaborative dynamics and collaborative actions. Together, collaborative dynamics and actions shape the overall quality and extent to which a CGR is developed and effective. Collaborative dynamics, represented by the innermost box with dotted lines, consist of three interactive components: principled engagement, shared motivation, and capacity for joint action. The three components of collaborative dynamics work together in an interactive and iterative way to produce collaborative actions or the steps taken in order to implement the shared purpose of the CGR. The actions of the CGR can lead to outcomes both within and external to the regime; thus, in the figure, arrows extend from the action box to demonstrate impacts (i.e., the results on the groundyf D Q G S R W H Q W L D O D G D S W D W L R Q W K e transformation of a complex situation or issueyf E R W K Z L W K L Q W K H V \ V W H P F R Q W H [ W D Q G W K e CGR itself. 6This content downloaded from 128.6.45.205 on Thu, 26 Aug 2021 02:44:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms го t_ О _Q J2 õ U О +■» JZ u <0 о t_ Q. О. < "03 TJ о S u '5b 5 u- o u "К о с <11 00 jU <11 (D -g S Ê < с с .2 О С С С д и 'V C¿ д 2 о I ïliïSïli < и (Л U и Í и и Û I I I ÖXyf _ « .S _ * ^ СЛ -*-• flyf VC CC3Ü^O>^ |>ОйХ>ЛООСЛ JS >> «G с £ ö JS § «G 5 £ с о щ 'I a I „ ® ¡ Í <£ § J5 » ^ »^^žs a» 1 «, § Он о .2 § „ S 3 £Р Í £Р ^ ~ » о -S -S ад § (u'C a» й «, c 3 'S о & . . .£ 2 .S о ^ ~ «3 о fa ' .с .S .S 00 о о 6 'о TS Од< о ^£&Р3012йЁвЗйй«-.ЗБг30асЗе35&4йё -а >< ¿ ^ > й о -Зд1! 2 §о g'5'S-ë.o & о ^£&Р3012йЁвЗйй«-.ЗБг30асЗе35&4йё > о ^ 5 g|oàtìtìhJ^^Ù^&ìfflUw2£SÌpqU о g !> о о .5 i i i li i i i i *5Ь « м ¿2 ^ £ м О ^ S о< £> (D '£ й Й Й -а Иyf « g s .2 s -s 'S в g § 'S .5 ? ^ö| > S С й-й 8 .5 § -о > о 5 > й-й &.S ° рн£ и и ° рн£> о § с fe о О _ -d.H о с о с .2 fe О <В -d.H й 'S ^ с _ g о .1 с .3 <В > S .£ 'S ã 2 _ 2 I Ч в .3 о |з > и S .£ о 'S lilll'âs! ã 2 2 Ч в ,£j cd 1 i i i ь =3 u „s « § „s 3 I E ь Í3 e -s « •§ 1 TL E ь Í3 .2 й •§ TL a S I-IJ5 .2 й i Il a .i 1 1 € а а о о i i i i О 3 J e о. s м "§ è* а> 5 2 о v .S •Ê « ŠT -ž & I В û -S « ŠT 8 g 'S В « S О о У g S £ с О О о У -a с II II СЛ -S S g 11 g ! I sM _ j a * 1 's S 1 Tg « é* ели MfiâSi§o|â§sô^^§>Cygl«> С^и&н^Рц0н^^нРнО&н0^(?и^им üOffiQ II I I III С S 1 Tyf L ¡ I Tyf i , J D i I i ! .a i i i и S £ o 7This content downloaded from 128.6.45.205 on Thu, 26 Aug 2021 02:44:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory In short, the structure of the integrative framework incorporates nested dimensions and their respective components. Specific elements within the components are listed in table 1 and described in more detail below. It is important to note that our framework incorporates many of the components identified in other frameworks but configures them in a way that posits causal relationships among the dimensions and their components and elements. As we describe the framework in more detail below, we relate it to other frameworks and present general propositions about how these dimensions, components, and elements interact. These propositions represent first steps in theory building (and can be used for fixture theory testingyf D V W K H \ V H W I R U W K J H Q H U D O S U H O L P L Q D U \ Z R U N L Q J D V V X P S W L R Q V D E R X W Z K D W I D F W R U V O H D d to collaboration and how the components work together to produce desired states. In this sense, we offer not only an integrative framework (i.e., we identify the overarching variables that are important to the study of collaborative governance and how they generally relateyf E X W D O V R R I I H U V R P H L Q L W L D O S D W K Z D \ V I R U L Q W H J U D W L Q J H [ L V W L Q J W K H R U \ D Q d building new theory based on the framework (i.e., through the propositions, we begin to develop theory, for example, about what factors lead to collaboration, what leads to the success and effectiveness of collaborative governance, and how a CGR may achieve adaptationyf 3 General System Context Collaborative governance is initiated and evolves within a multilayered context of political, legal, socioeconomic, environmental, and other influences (Borrini-Feyerabend 1996yf . This external system context creates opportunities and constraints and influences the general parameters within which a CGR unfolds. Not only does the system context shape the overall CGR but the regime itself can also affect the system context through the impact of its collaborative actions.4 Researchers have recognized several chief elements in the system context that may distinguish or influence the nature and prospects of a CGR, including resource conditions in need of improving, increasing, or limiting (e.g., Ostrom 1990yf S R O L F \ D Q G O H J D O I U D P H - works, including administrative, regulatory, or judicial (e.g., Bingham 2008yf S U L R U I D L O X U e to address the issues through conventional channels and authorities (e.g., Bryson and Crosby 2008yf S R O L W L F D O G \ Q D P L F V D Q G S R Z H U U H O D W L R Q V Z L W K L Q F R P P X Q L W L H V D Q G D P R Q J / across levels of government (e.g., Ansell and Gash 2008yf G H J U H H R I F R Q Q H F W H G Q H V V Z L W K L n 3 This discussion is based on Ostrom's (2005yf G L V W L Q F W L R Q V D P R Q J I U D P H Z R U N V W K H R U L H V D Q G P R G H O V ) U D P H Z R U N s specify general sets of variables (and the relationships among the variablesyf W K D W D U H R I L Q W H U H V W W R D U H V H D U F K H U 7 K H R U L H s are more specific and provide an interpretive structure for frameworks. Theories enable the researcher to make working assumptions about how the variables in a framework interact, for example, to explain why events occur or to make predictions about relationships or phenomena. Finally, models are even more specific than theories and allow researchers to make precise assumptions about a limited set of variables, for example, to test hypotheses and predict outcomes. 4 For example, in the absence of federal action on climate change issues, state and local governments began developing their own climate change policies. In 2003, then New York Governor George Pataki invited fellow governors in the Northeast to explore the possibility of a regional climate change strategy. The result was the development of the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative (RGGIyf , Q W K L V F D V H W K H V \ V W H P F R Q W H [ W L Q Z K L F K F R O O D E R U D W L R n unfolded was shaped by local, state, national, and international politics, the lack of federal law and action, environmental concerns, and other issues. In turn, RGGI changed the landscape of the system context by altering political, legal, regulatory, socioeconomic, environmental, and other forces in multiple northeastern states (Rabe 2010yf . 8This content downloaded from 128.6.45.205 on Thu, 26 Aug 2021 02:44:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Emerson et al. Integrative Framework for Collaborative Governance and across existing networks (e.g., Selin and Chavez 1995yf K L V W R U L F O H Y H O V R I F R Q I O L F t among recognized interests and the resulting levels of trust and impact on working relationships (e.g., Ansell and Gash 2008; Radin 1996; Thomson and Perry 2006yf D Q d socioeconomic and cultural health and diversity (e.g., Sabatier et al. 2005yf . The system context is represented in this framework, not as a set of starting conditions but as a surrounding three-dimensional space because external conditions (e.g., an election, economic downturn, extreme weather event, or newly enacted regulationyf P D \ L Q I O X H Q F e the dynamics and performance of collaboration not only at the outset but at any time during the life of the CGR, thus opening up new possibilities or posing unanticipated challenges. Drivers Although the literature broadly recognizes that the "conditions present at the outset of collaboration can either facilitate or discourage cooperation among stakeholders and between agencies and stakeholders" (Ansell and Gash 2008, 550yf P D Q \ I U D P H Z R U N V W H Q d to conflate system context and conditions with the specific drivers of collaboration (e.g., Ansell and Gash 2008; Bentrup 2001; Thomson and Perry 2006; for an exception, see Bryson, Crosby, and Stone 2006yf , Q F R Q W U D V W R X U I U D P H Z R U N V H S D U D W H V W K H F R Q W H [ W X D l variables from essential drivers, without which the impetus for collaboration would not successfully unfold. These drivers include leadership, consequential incentives, interdependence, and uncertainty. Leadership , the first essential driver, refers to the presence of an identified leader who is in a position to initiate and help secure resources and support for a CGR. The leader may, by virtue of her own stature, be a member of one of the parties or the deciding official or may be located within a trusted boundary organization. Regardless, she should possess a commitment to collaborative problem solving, a willingness not to advocate for a particular solution, and exhibit impartiality with respect to the preferences of participants (Bryson, Crosby, and Stone 2006; Selin and Chavez 1995yf , Q D G G L W L R Q W K H Z L O O L Q J Q H V V R f a leader to absorb the high (and potentially constrainingyf W U D Q V D F W L R Q F R V W V R I L Q L W L D W L Q g a collaborative effort, for example, by providing staffing, technologies, and other resources may help reinforce the endeavor (e.g., Schneider et al. 2003yf . Consequential incentives refer to either internal (problems, resource needs, interests, or opportunitiesyf R U H [ W H U Q D O V L W X D W L R Q D O R U L Q V W L W X W L R Q D O F U L V H V W K U H D W V R U R S S R U W X Q L W L H V \f drivers for collaborative action. Such incentives are consequential in that the presenting issues are salient to participants, the timing or pressure for solutions is ripe, and the absence of attention to the incentives may have negative impacts (Selin and Chavez 1995yf , W V K R X O d be noted, however, that not all consequential incentives are negative. For example, the availability of a grant or new funding opportunity may lead to the development of a collaborative initiative. Nevertheless, such incentives (positive or negativeyf P X V W H [ L V t to induce leaders and participants to engage together. Interdependence , or when individuals and organizations are unable to accomplish something on their own, is a broadly recognized precondition for collaborative action (Gray 1989; Thomson and Perry 2006yf , Q D V H Q V H W K L V L V W K H X O W L P D W H F R Q V H T X H Q W L D O L Q F H Q W L Y H . This driver is referred to as "sector failure" by Bryson, Crosby, and Stone (2006yf D Q G D s "constraints on participation" by Ansell and Gash (2008yf . The final driver, uncertainty , is a primary challenge for managing "wicked" societal problems (Koppenjan and Klijn 2004; Rittel and Webber 1973yf 8 Q F H U W D L Q W \ W K D W F D Q Q R W E e 9This content downloaded from 128.6.45.205 on Thu, 26 Aug 2021 02:44:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 10 Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory resolved internally can drive groups to collaborate in order to reduce, diffuse, and share risk. Collective uncertainty about how to manage societal problems is also related to the driver of interdependence. Were parties or organizations endowed with perfect information about a problem and its solution, they would be able to act independently to pursue their interests or respond to risk (Bentrup 2001yf 7 K H U H F D Q D O V R E H L Q G L Y L G X D O X Q F H U W D L Q W \ D E R X t the extent to which conventional avenues for solutions or satisfaction (sometimes referred to as the Best Alternative to a Negotiated Agreement in conflict management literatureyf F D n be relied on to produce the intended result. Our first proposition concerns the extent to which these drivers are needed to initiate a CGR: Proposition One: One or more of the drivers of leadership, consequential incentives, interdependence, or uncertainty are necessary for a CGR to begin. The more drivers present and recognized by participants, the more likely a CGR will be initiated. Collaborative Governance Regime As previously described, the integrative framework introduces the term CGR, to denote a system in which cross-boundary collaboration represents the predominate mode for conduct, decision making, and activity. The form and direction of the CGR is shaped initially by the drivers that emerge from the system context; however, the development of the CGR, as well as the degree to which it is effective, is influenced over time by its two components: collaborative dynamics and collaborative actions. Below, we describe these two components, as well as the various elements embedded within them. Collaborative Dynamics Essential drivers energize or induce the convening of participants by reducing the initial for- mative costs of collective action and setting the collaborative dynamics in motion. These dy- namics and the actions they produce over time constitute a CGR. Several scholars portray collaborative processes as a linear sequence of cognitive steps or stages that occur over time from problem definition to direction setting and implementation (Daniels and Walker 2001; Gray 1 989; Selin and Chavez 1 995yf , Q F R Q W U D V W D Q G F R Q V L V W H Q W Z L W K $ Q V H O O D Q G * D V K \f and Thomson and Perry (2006yf Z H Y L H Z W K H V W D J H V Z L W K L Q F R O O D E R U D W L Y H G \ Q D P L F V D V F \ F O L F D l or iterative interactions. We focus on three interacting components of collaborative dynamics: principled engagement, shared motivation, and capacity for joint action. Principled Engagement Principled engagement occurs over time and may include different stakeholders at different points and take place in face-to-face or virtual formats, cross-organizational networks, or private and public meetings, among other settings. Through principled engagement, people with differing content, relational, and identity goals work across their respective institutional, sectoral, or jurisdictional boundaries to solve problems, resolve conflicts, or create value (Cahn 1994; Cupach and Canary 1997; Lulofs and Cahn 2000yf $ O W K R X J h face-to-face dialogue is advantageous at the outset, it is not always essential, particularly when conflict may be low and shared values and objectives quickly surface. This content downloaded from 128.6.45.205 on Thu, 26 Aug 2021 02:44:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Emerson et al. Integrative Framework for Collaborative Governance We call this component in our framework "principled" engagement to adhere to the basic espoused principles articulated broadly in both practice and research, including fair and civil discourse, open and inclusive communications, balanced by representation of "all relevant and significant different interests" (Innes and Booher 1999, 419yf D Q G L Q I R U P H G E y the perspectives and knowledge of all participants (see also Ansell and Gash 2008; Carlson 2007; Henton et al. 2005; Leach 2006; O'Leary, Bingham, and Gerard 2006; Susskind, McKearnan, and Thomas-Larmer 1999yf 5 Before specifying the nested elements within principled engagement, it is important to discuss the participants. Who the participants are and who they represent are of signal importance to collaboration. Participants may also be called members, stakeholders, parties, partners, or collaborators, depending on the context and objectives of the CGR. They may represent themselves, a client, a constituency, a decision maker, a public agency, an NGO, a business or corporation, a community, or the public at large. Their selection may vary considerably, ranging from state-based participants (e.g., expert administrators and elected representativesyf W R P L Q L S X E O L F V H J S U R I H V V L R Q D O R U O D \ V W D N H K R O G H U V R U U D Q G R P O y selected, self-selected, or recruited individualsyf D Q G G L I I X V H P H P E H U V R I W K H S X E O L F ) X Q g 2006yf 7 K H L U Q X P E H U P D \ U D Q J H I U R P W R R U P R U H ( P H U V R Q H W D O \f. Moreover, each participant brings a set of individual attitudes, values, interests, and knowledge in addition to the cultures, missions, and mandates of the organizations or constituents they represent (Bardach 2001yf . There is general agreement in practice and research that getting the "right" people to the table is important (Ansell and Gash 2008; Carlson 2007; Carpenter and Kennedy 2001; Emerson et al. 2009; Susskind, McKearnan, and Thomas-Larmer 1999yf , Q F O X V L R Q D Q d diversity are valued not only as normative organizing principles but also for instrumental reasons - they give voice to multiple perspectives and different interests, allowing the development of more thoughtful decisions that take a broader view of who will benefit or be harmed by an action (Beierle and Cayford 2002; Sirianni 2009yf 0 R U H R Y H U W K H U H O - ative and combined power of the participants can enable or disable subsequent agreements or collective courses of action.6 Principled engagement occurs over time through the iteration of four basic process elements: discovery, definition, deliberation, and determination. These build on collabo- rative learning phases by Daniels and Walker (2001yf D Q G P D \ E H W K R X J K W R I D V H O H P H Q W V R f a dynamic social learning process (e.g., Bandura 1977yf 7 K U R X J K W K L V L W H U D W L Y H S U R F H V V , collaboration partners develop a shared sense of purpose and a shared theory of action for achieving that purpose. This shared theory of action includes the group's understanding 5 We have elevated "principled engagement" to the framework level (as opposed to Ostrom' s [2005] theory levelyf because it is a fundamental component within the definition of collaborative governance. Arguably, not all engagement will in fact be principled, that is, the de jure notion of principled engagement may not be what happens in de facto engagement. Nevertheless, the notion of principled engagement is consistent with the general definitions of collaborative governance, as well as our broader definition of collaborative governance. Moreover, the elements of principled engagement in this framework are articulated broadly enough to allow for different theories of engagement to be applied and different models to be tested. 6 It should be noted that increasing diversity in participation may have undesired consequences as well. In some situations, more diversity can generate higher levels of conflict and erode principled engagement, whereas in other situations, less diversity can lead to different, though not necessarily inferior actions and accomplishments (Korfmacher 2000; Schlager and Blomquist 2008; Steelman and Carmin 2002yf . 11This content downloaded from 128.6.45.205 on Thu, 26 Aug 2021 02:44:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 12 Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory of the size of the problem or challenge it is addressing, as well as the scope and scale of the group's chosen activities or interventions (Koontz et al. 2004; Leach and Pelkey 2001yf . Discovery refers to the revealing of individual and shared interests, concerns, and values, as well as to the identification and analysis of relevant and significant information and its implications. At the outset, discovery may be focused on identifying shared interests; later, it might be observed in joint fact-finding and more analytic investigation (Ehrmann and Stinson 1999; Ozawa 1991yf 7 K H G H I L Q L W L R Q S U R F H V V F K D U D F W H U L ] H V W K e continuous efforts to build shared meaning by articulating common purpose and objectives; agreeing on the concepts and terminology participants will use to describe and discuss problems and opportunities; clarifying and adjusting tasks and expectations of one another; and setting forth shared criteria with which to assess information and alternatives (for discussions, see Bentrup 2001; Pahl-Wostl 2007yf . Deliberation, or candid and reasoned communication, is broadly celebrated as a hall- mark and essential ingredient of successful engagement. The quality of deliberation, especially when participants have differing interests and perspectives, depends on both the skillful advocacy of individual and represented interests and the effectiveness of conflict resolution strategies and interventions, described in a recent National Research Council (2009yf U H S R U W D V G H O L E H U D W L R Q Z L W K D Q D O \ V L V + D U G F R Q Y H U V D W L R Q V F R Q V W U X F W L Y e self-assertion, asking and answering challenging questions, and expressing honest disagreements are part and parcel of effective communication across boundaries. Collaborative governance creates the "safe" space for such deliberation to take place. Advocates of deliberative democracy, public engagement, and alternative dispute resolution agree on the importance of enabling the exercise of meaningful "voice" through deliberation. As Roberts (2004, 332yf Q R W H V ' H O L E H U D W L R Q L V Q R W W K H D J J U H J D W L R Q R f interests.' It requires thoughtful examination of issues, listening to others' perspectives, and coming to a public judgment on what represents the common good." Finally, principled engagement incorporates the processes of making enumerable joint determinations, including procedural decisions (e.g., setting agendas, tabling a discussion, assigning a work groupyf D Q G V X E V W D Q W L Y H G H W H U P L Q D W L R Q V H J U H D F K L Q J D J U H H P H Q W V R n action items or final recommendationsyf 6 X E V W D Q W L Y H G H W H U P L Q D W L R Q V D U H R I W H Q F R Q V L G H U H d one of the outputs or end products of collaboration or conflict resolution (Dukes 2004; Emerson et al. 2009yf , Q D Q R Q J R L Q J & * 5 K R Z H Y H U P D Q \ V X E V W D Q W L Y H G H W H U P L Q D W L R Q s are made over time; these are integrated in the framework as a repeating element within principled engagement. Collaboration theory and practice suggest that determinations produced through strong engagement processes will be fairer and more durable, robust, and efficacious (Innes and Booher 1999; Sipe and Stiftel 1995; Susskind and Cruikshank 1987yf + R Z H Y H U , there is limited research on the quality of collaborative determinations and the extent to which they lead to actions required for implementation (Bingham and O'Leary 2008yf 0 R V t practitioners and researchers, however, advance consensus building as the foundational method for making group determinations (e.g., Innes and Booher, 1999; Susskind and Cruikshank 1987yf D O W K R X J K W K L V G R H V Q R W P H D Q W K D W F R Q V H Q V X V D V D G H F L V L R Q U X O H L V D O Z D \ s required or achieved (Susskind, McKearnan, and Thomas-Larmer 1999yf . Collaborative engagement processes have been studied from various disciplinary lenses, and observers identify numerous positive outcomes from successful engagement beyond the overall quality of determinations, such as improved clarity on key issues This content downloaded from 128.6.45.205 on Thu, 26 Aug 2021 02:44:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Emerson et al. Integrative Framework for Collaborative Governance 1 3 and concerns; effective management of differences and conflicts; enhanced trust and mutual respect built among the parties; increased social, operational, and decision making capacity; better integration of relevant knowledge into deliberations and decisions; and greater perceived legitimacy within and outside of the collaboration (Agranoff and McGuire 2003; Bryson, Crosby, and Stone 2006; Emerson et al. 2009; Fung 2006; Leach and Sabatier 2005; Milward and Provan 2000yf 6 R P H V F K R O D U V F R P E L Q H W K H V H R X W F R P H s dynamically with engagement processes, whereby a "virtuous cycle" is set in motion (e.g., Ansell and Gash 2008; Huxham 2003; Imperial 2005yf , Q R X U I U D P H Z R U N Z H X Q S D F k this dynamic by distinguishing the engagement component from both the shared motivational benefits it produces and the subsequent capacity for joint action that is generated. In other words, within our collaborative governance framework, the dynamic cycling of discovery, definition, deliberation, and determination during principled engagement creates and reinforces shared motivation and builds the needed capacity for joint action. Proposition Two: Principled engagement is generated and sustained by the interactive processes of discovery, definition, deliberation, and determination. The effectiveness of principled engagement is determined, in part, by the quality of these interactive processes. Shared Motivation We define shared motivation as a self-reinforcing cycle consisting of four elements: mutual trust, understanding, internal legitimacy, and commitment. All but legitimacy are included in the Ansell and Gash (2008yf F R Q I L J X U D W L R Q R I F R O O D E R U D W L Y H S U R F H V V 6 K D U H G P R W L Y D W L R n highlights the interpersonal and relational elements of the collaborative dynamics and is sometimes referred to as social capital (Colman 1988; Putnam 2000; Putnam, Leonardi, and Nanetti 1993yf 6 K D U H G P R W L Y D W L R Q L V L Q S D U W L Q L W L D W H G E \ S U L Q F L S O H G H Q J D J H P H Q W D Q G L Q W K D t sense, it is an intermediate outcome; however, once initiated, shared motivation also re- inforces or accelerates the principled engagement process (Huxham and Vangen 2005yf . The first element of shared motivation (and the initial outgrowth of principled engagementyf L V W K H G H Y H O R S P H Q W R I W U X V W Z K L F K K D S S H Q V R Y H U W L P H D V S D U W L H V Z R U N W R J H W K H U , get to know each other, and prove to each other that they are reasonable, predictable, and dependable (Fisher and Brown 1989yf 7 U X V W K D V E H H Q D O R Q J U H F R J Q L ] H G V L Q H T X D Q R Q R f collaboration (Huxham and Vangen 2005; Koppenjan and Klijn 2004; Leach and Sabatier 2005; Ostrom 1998yf , Q Q H W Z R U N V I R U H [ D P S O H W U X V W K D V E H H Q I R X Q G W R E H L Q V W U X P H Q W D O L n reducing transaction costs, improving investments and stability in relations, and stimulating learning, knowledge exchange, and innovation (Koppenjan and Klijn 2004yf : e conceptualize the mechanism by which trust produces such outcomes as an initial pivotal element within the cycle of shared motivation, that is, trust generates mutual understanding, which in turn generates legitimacy and finally commitment. Trust enables people to go beyond their own personal, institutional, and jurisdictional frames of reference and perspec- tives toward understanding other peoples' interests, needs, values, and constraints (Bardach 1998; Ring and Van de Ven 1994; Thomson and Perry 2006yf . This forms the basis of mutual understanding , the second element in shared motiva- tion. At an interpersonal level, trust enables people to see and then appreciate differences in others. It enables people to reveal themselves to others and hence be seen and appreciated This content downloaded from 128.6.45.205 on Thu, 26 Aug 2021 02:44:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 14 Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory by them (Daniels and Walker 2001; Gray 1989yf 0 X W X D O X Q G H U V W D Q G L Q J L V Q R W V K D U H d understanding" as discussed by Ansell and Gash (2008yf Z K H U H S D U W L F L S D Q W V D J U H H R n a shared set of values or goals; rather, mutual understanding specifically refers to the ability to understand and respect others' positions and interests even when one might not agree. In turn, mutual understanding generates a sense of interpersonal validation and cognitive legitimacy (the third elementyf U H I H U U H G W R D V L Q W H U Q D O O H J L W L P D F \ E \ 3 U R Y D n and Milward (1995yf D Q G D V D S U R F H V V F R P S R Q H Q W L Q % U \ V R Q & U R V E \ D Q G 6 W R Q H \f. The confirmation that participants in a collective endeavor are trustworthy and credible, with compatible and interdependent interests, legitimizes and motivates ongoing collaboration. The informal interpersonal norms of trust and reciprocity that Thomson and Perry (2006yf G L V F X V V J X L G H W K R V H L Q W H U D F W L R Q V D Q G I L L U W K H U U H L Q I R U F H F R Q I L G H Q F H L n the legitimacy and efficacy of the collaborative dynamics. This leads to creating bonds of shared commitment (the fourth elementyf Z K L F K H Q D E O H S D U W L F L S D Q W V W R F U R V V W K e organizational, sectoral, and/or jurisdictional boundaries that previously separated them and commit to a shared path. Ansell and Gash (2008, 17yf D O V R G L V W L Q J X L V K F R P P L W P H Q t to the process" as a key factor in collaborative dynamics. Proposition Three: Repeated, quality interactions through principled engagement will help foster trust, mutual understanding, internal legitimacy, and shared commitment, thereby generating and sustaining shared motivation. Proposition Four: Once generated, shared motivation will enhance and help sustain principled engagement and vice versa in a "virtuous cycle." Capacity for Joint Action The purpose of collaboration is to generate desired outcomes together that could not be accomplished separately. As Himmelman (1994yf G H V F U L E H V L W F R O O D E R U D W L R Q L V H Q J D J L Q g in cooperative activities to enhance the capacity of both self and others to achieve a common purpose. Thus, the CGR must generate a new capacity for joint action that did not exist before and sustain or grow that capacity for the duration of the shared purpose. The necessary capacity building is specified during principled engagement, derived from the participants' explicit or tacit theory of action needed to accomplish their collaborative purpose, and likely to be influenced by the scope and scale of the group's objectives and activities. This new capacity is also the basis for group empowerment, which is frequently discussed as a democratic principle underlying collaboration (e.g., Leach 2006yf . Borrowing from Saint-Onge and Armstrong's (2004, 17yf G H I L Q L W L R Q R I F D S D E L O L W L H V I R r conductive organizations, we view the capacity for joint action as "a collection of cross- functional elements that come together to create the potential for taking effective action" and serve "as the link between strategy and performance" (2004, 19yf , Q R X U I U D P H Z R U N , capacity for joint action is conceptualized as the combination of four necessary elements: procedural and institutional arrangements, leadership, knowledge, and resources. All the collaborative frameworks we studied recognize the importance of formal and informal rules and protocols, institutional design, and other structural dimensions to on-going collaboration. Most also identify leadership as an important element. The levels of these elements must be sufficient enough to accomplish agreed upon goals. Moreover, capacity for joint action can be viewed as an intermediate outcome of the interacting cycles of principled engagement and shared motivation. However, as joint capacity develops, it This content downloaded from 128.6.45.205 on Thu, 26 Aug 2021 02:44:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Emerson et al. Integrative Framework for Collaborative Governance 1 5 can also strengthen or improve the engagement and shared motivation cycles, and in synergy, assure more effective actions and impacts. One or more of the elements of capacity for joint action may be offered upfront as an inducement to collaboration by the initiating leader and/or be developed over time through the interaction of principled engagement and shared motivation. Procedural and institutional arrangements encompass the range of process protocols and organizational structures necessary to manage repeated interactions over time. The conflict resolution literature indentifies dimensions such as agreements to mediate ground rules, operating protocols, decision rules, and so forth, but these are insufficient for longer term collaborations where informal norms must be supplemented with more formal institutional design factors such as charters, by-laws, rules, and regulations. In other words, larger, more complex, and long-lived collaborative networks require more explicit structures and protocols for the administration and management of work (Milward and Provan 2000, 2006yf . These procedural and institutional arrangements must be defined at both the intraorganizational level (i.e., how a single group or organization will govern and manage itself in the collaborative initiativeyf D Q G D W W K H L Q W H U R U J D Q L ] D W L R Q D O O H Y H O L H K R Z W K H J U R X S s of organizations will govern and manage together in the CGR and integrate with external decision making authoritiesyf , Q J H Q H U D O W K H L Q W H U Q D O D X W K R U L W \ V W U X F W X U H R I F R O O D E R U D W L Y e institutions tends to be less hierarchical and stable, and more complex and fluid, than those found in traditional bureaucracies (Bryson, Crosby, and Stone 2006; Huxham and Vangen 2005yf 6 X F K V W U X F W X U H V D Q G S U R W R F R O V P D \ Y D U \ E \ I X Q F W L R Q I R U H [ D P S O H W D N L Q J R Q W K e shape of informational, developmental, outreach, or action networks (Agranoff and McGuire 2003yf D Q G E \ I R U P I R U H [ D P S O H E H L Q J D G P L Q L V W H U H G D V D V H O I P D Q D J L Q J V \ V W H P , by a designated lead agency or agencies, or with the creation of a new governmental structure (Milward and Provan 2006yf . The protocols that govern collaborative endeavors may be informal "norms of reciprocity" and/or more formal rules of network interactions (Thomson and Perry 2006yf 7 K H \ P D \ D O V R G L V W L Q J X L V K L Q W H U D F W L R Q U X O H V I U R P D U H Q D U X O H V L Q Q H W Z R U N V . R S S H Q M D n and Klijn 2004yf 7 K H F R P P R Q S R R O U H V R X U F H O L W H U D W X U H K D V F R Q W U L E X W H G J U H D W O \ W R R X r understanding of the importance of rules, including constitutional rules, laying out the basic scope and authorities for joint effort, decision making rules, and operating procedures (Bingham 2009; Ostrom 1990yf . The second element in capacity for joint action is leadership. The importance of leadership in collaborative governance is widely confirmed (Ansell and Gash 2008; Bingham and O'Leary 2008; Carlson 2007; Saint-Onge and Armstrong 2004; Susskind and Cruikshank 1987yf / H D G H U V K L S F D Q E H D Q H [ W H U Q D O G U L Y H U D V Z H S R V L W H G H D U O L H U \f, an essential ingredient of collaborative governance itself, and a significant outgrowth of collaboration. Moreover, collaborative governance demands and cultivates multiple opportunities and roles for leadership (Agranoff and McGuire 2003; Bryson, Crosby, and Stone 2006yf 7 K H V H L Q F O X G H W K H O H D G H U V K L S U R O H V R I V S R Q V R U F R Q Y H Q H U I D F L O L W D W R U P H - diator, representative of an organization or constituency, science translator, technologist, and public advocate, among others. Certain leadership roles are essential at the outset, others more critical during moments of deliberation or conflict, and still others in championing the collaborative determinations through to implementation (Agranoff 2006; Bryson, Crosby, and Stone 2006; Carlson 2007yf . This content downloaded from 128.6.45.205 on Thu, 26 Aug 2021 02:44:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 16 Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory Knowledge is the third element in the capacity for joint action. In many ways, it is the currency of collaboration. It is knowledge, once guarded, that is shared with others; knowledge jointly needed that is generated together. It is contested knowledge that requires full consideration; and incomplete knowledge that must be balanced and enhanced with new knowledge. In essence, collaboration requires the aggregation, separation, and reassembly of data and information, as well as the generation of new, shared knowledge. "Knowledge is information combined with understanding and capability: it lives in the minds of people . . . Knowledge guides action, whereas information and data can merely inform or confuse" (Groff and Jones 2003yf & D O O H G S D U W R I W K H D V V H W V R I K X P D Q F D S L W D O E y Agranoff (2008, 165yf W K H W H U P N Q R Z O H G J H L Q W K L V I U D P H Z R U N U H I H U V W R W K H V R F L D O F D S L W D l of shared knowledge that has been weighed, processed, and integrated with the values and judgments of all participants. Ansell and Gash (2008, 544yf Q R W H $ V N Q R Z O H G J H E H F R P H V L Q F U H D V L Q J O \ V S H F L D O L ] H d and distributed and as institutional infrastructures become more complex and interdependent, the demand for collaboration increases." Scholars seem to agree, and several have studied and written explicitly about the importance of knowledge management to collaboration across networks (e.g., Agranoff 2007, 2008; Cross and Parker 2004yf ) R r Saint-Onge and Armstrong (2004yf W K H D E L O L W \ W R W U D Q V P L W K L J K T X D O L W \ N Q R Z O H G J e effectively within and across organizations is the essence of "conductivity" in high-per- formance organizations and networks. Knowledge is also the central element in adaptive resource management models, where conditions of scientific or resource uncertainty lead parties to cooperate in management experiments to test and build knowledge for better and more enduring management practices (Holling 1978yf . Resources are the final element of the capacity for joint action. One benefit of collaboration is its potential for sharing and leveraging scarce resources (Thomson and Perry 2006yf $ G H T X D W H E X G J H W V X S S R U W D Q G R W K H U Q H H G H G U H V R X U F H V D U H D O V R L Q V W U X P H Q W D l to successful collaboration (Lubell, Leach, and Sabatier 2009yf 8 V H I X O U H V R X U F H V P D y include funding, time, technical and logistical support; administrative and organizational assistance; requisite skills for analysis or implementation; and needed expertise, among others. Power can also be viewed as a resource and, like other resources, is almost always distributed unevenly across participants (Bryson, Crosby, and Stone 2006; Huxham and Vangen 2005yf 5 H V R X U F H G L V S D U L W L H V D P R Q J S D U W L F L S D Q W V D U H R I W H Q K L J K O L J K W H G L Q F U R V V F X O - tural settings, where language, customs, and culture can present barriers to engagement. Through the collaborative dynamics, these resources can be leveraged and redistributed as shared resources to affect the common goals of the CGR. The perceived and real fairness, legitimacy, and efficacy of CGRs can depend on how well these resource differences are managed. Many researchers see the ways in which administrative resources are marshaled and configured as critical for collaboration success (Milward and Provan 2000; Thomson and Perry 2006yf . Proposition Five: Principled engagement and shared motivation will stimulate the development of institutional arrangements, leadership, knowledge, and resources, thereby generating and sustaining capacity for joint action. Proposition Six: The necessary levels for the four elements of capacity for joint action are determined by the CGR' s purpose, shared theory of action, and targeted outcomes. This content downloaded from 128.6.45.205 on Thu, 26 Aug 2021 02:44:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Emerson et al. Integrative Framework for Collaborative Governance 17 We conclude our description of collaborative dynamics with a summary proposition. Proposition Seven: The quality and extent of collaborative dynamics depends on the productive and self-reinforcing interactions among principled engagement, shared motivation, and the capacity for joint action. Collaborative Actions Collaborative governance is "generally initiated with an instrumental purpose in mind" (Huxham et al. 2000, 340yf W K D W L V W R S U R S H O D F W L R Q V W K D W F R X O G Q R W K D Y H E H H Q D W W D L Q H d by any of the organizations acting alone" (Huxham 2003, 403; see also Agranoff and McGuire 2003; Bingham and O'Leary 2008yf & R O O D E R U D W L Y H D F W L R Q V V K R X O G E H D W W K H K H D U t of any collaborative governance framework, but they have received limited attention and are often left unspecified (Thomas and Koontz, 201 1yf : K H Q D G G U H V V H G F R O O D E R U D W L Y H D F - tion is usually seen as the major outcome of a linear process and is sometimes conflated with impacts. However, "Processes and outcomes cannot be neatly separated in consensus building [and CGRs] because the process matters in and of itself and because the process and outcome are likely to be tied together" (Innes and Booher 1999, 415yf . Nevertheless, effective CGRs should provide new mechanisms for collective action (e.g., Donahue 2004yf G H W H U P L Q H G E \ F R O O D E R U D W L R Q S D U W Q H U V L Q D F F R U G D Q F H Z L W K W K H L r expressed or implied theory of action for accomplishing their preferred outcomes. Depending on the context and charge of the CGR, such actions may include, for example, securing endorsements, educating constituents or the public, enacting policy measures (new laws or regulationsyf P D U V K D O O L Q J H [ W H U Q D O U H V R X U F H V G H S O R \ L Q J V W D I I V L W L Q J D Q d permitting facilities, building or cleaning up, carrying out new management practices, monitoring implementation, and enforcing compliance. Some CGRs have very broad aims (e.g., taking actions related to strategic development or within a particular policy issue or areayf Z K H U H D V R W K H U V K D Y H Q D U U R Z H U J R D O V H J W D N L Q J D F W L R Q R Q D S D U W L F X O D U S U R M H F W R r gathering and analyzing specific informationyf + X [ K D P H W D O \f. Collaborative actions may be conducted in concert by all the partners or their agents, by individual partners carrying out tasks agreed on through the CGR or by external entities responding to recommendations or directions from the CGR. The appropriateness of the actions should be viewed in light of the CGR' s shared theory of action and understood within the system context, where such actions by individual people or organizations would not otherwise be taken. Collaborative action will be difficult to accomplish, much less assess, if shared goals and an operating rationale for taking action are not made explicit. "Common wisdom" implies "that it is necessary to be clear about the aims of joint working if partners are to work together to operationalize policies .... The common practice, however, appears to be that the variety of organizational and individual agendas that are present in collaborative situations make it difficult to agree on aims in practice" (Huxham 2003, 404yf . Research suggests several factors affect the likelihood that collaborative action will be taken or implemented, including many of the elements we have integrated into collaborative dynamics, such as leadership, diverse representation, and power (e.g., Huxham 2003; Huxham et al. 2000yf % H F D X V H V X F K D F W L R Q V R I W H Q W D N H S O D F H R Y H U D O R Q J S H U L R G R I W L P H D Q G R I W H Q E y individual partners or external agents subject to other forces outside the CGR, it can be difficult to trace and attribute influence or causation to the CGR (Conley and Moote This content downloaded from 128.6.45.205 on Thu, 26 Aug 2021 02:44:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 18 Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 2003; Emerson et al. 2003; Koontz and Thomas 2006yf 7 K H V H P H W K R G R O R J L F D O F K D O O H Q J H s and the conceptual isolation of actions as outside of the collaborative process have limited the study of collaborative action and the performance of collaborative governance. In this framework, we specify collaborative action and its integration within a CGR. Proposition Eight : Collaborative actions are more likely to be implemented if 1yf a shared theory of action is identified explicitly among the collaboration partners and 2yf W K H F R O O D E R U D W L Y H G \ Q D P L F V I X Q F W L R Q W o generate the needed capacity for joint action. Impacts The impacts derived from CGRs have also been challenging to operationalize, in part because of the confusion in the literature about the impacts, effects, outputs, and/or outcomes of collaboration (Thomas and Koontz, 2011yf ) R U H [ D P S O H , Q Q H V D Q G % R R K H U \f refer to a range of direct and indirect impacts as first-, second-, and third-order effects that may emerge from a collaborative initiative. Similarly, Lubell, Leach, and Sabatier (2009yf U H I H U W R G L I I H U H Q W N L Q G V R I I L U V W R U G H U V H F R Q G R U G H U D Q G W K L U G R U G H U R X W S X W V 3 U R E - lematically, these constructions of impacts/effects/outputs tend to conflate collaborative dynamics with the overall CGR and its outcomes. For the theory and practice of collaborative governance to develop, we need to generate better conceptual clarity about impacts. In our framework, we focus the definition of impacts on what Innes and Booher (1999, 419yf F O D V V L I \ D V W K H W K L U G R U G H U H I I H F W R I U H V X O W V R Q W K H J U R X Q G , P S D F W V U H V X O W I U R P W K e actions spurred by collaborative dynamics. Impacts are intentional (and unintentionalyf changes of state within the system context; they are alterations in a preexisting or projected condition that has been deemed undesirable or in need of change. Impacts may also include the added value of a new social good or technological innovation developed by collaborative action. Impacts can be physical, environmental, social, economic, and/or political. They can be specific, discrete, and short term or they can be more broadly cast, cumulative in nature, and with longer term impacts. The former is much easier to measure and confirm, the latter more challenging to verify and evaluate. When accountability for collaborative outcomes is deemed important, these impacts are likely to be more explicit and measurable. Preferably, the nature and extent of the impacts are consistent with the desired outcomes targeted by the collaborative partners during the iterative principled en- gagement process. The absence of impacts, as well as unintended impacts (both negative and positiveyf F D Q R F F X U D Q G V K R X O G E H D F F R X Q W H G I R U . Proposition Nine: The impacts resulting from collaborative action are likely to be closer to the targeted outcomes with fewer unintended negative consequences when they are specified and derived from a shared theory of action during collaborative dynamics. Adaptation Collaborative governance is frequently advocated because of its potential to transform the context of a complex situation or issue. Indeed, one of the "most important consequences This content downloaded from 128.6.45.205 on Thu, 26 Aug 2021 02:44:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Emerson et al. Integrative Framework for Collaborative Governance 19 [of collaborative governance] may be to change the direction of a complex, uncertain, evolving situation, and to help move a community toward higher levels of social and environmental importance" (Innes and Booher 1999, 413yf , Q R X U I U D P H Z R U N Z H L G H Q W L I y such potential transformative change as adaptation to impacts fostered by CGRs. For example, based on the impacts of collaborative action, problems are solved (or notyf , new research findings confirm selected management practices (or do notyf D Q G G L I I H U H Q t sets of challenges or opportunities arise. Each of these may alter the general system context. We also propose in our framework the potential for adaptation in the CGR itself. This may occur indirectly as a result of changes in the system context (e.g., thus changing the drivers to collaborationyf R U G L U H F W O \ L Q U H V S R Q V H W R W K H S H U F H L Y H G H I I H F W L Y H Q H V V R I D F W L R Q V D Q d impacts (e.g., leading to a new charge or mandate, the addition of new stakeholders, a new round of knowledge generation or resource leverage, or the decision to disband the collaborationyf , Q Q H V D Q G % R R K H U \f classify many of these adaptations as third-order effects. Adaptive resource management, which predates the broader conceptualization of collaborative governance, posits the same kind of feedback mechanism (Holling 1978yf in more resilient, decentralized systems where conditions of uncertainty or limited scientific knowledge may reduce the utility of permanent management investments or strategies. Less attention has been given, however, to the adaptation of the institutional arrangements themselves or the attendant CGRs (Heikkila and Gerlak 2005; Karkkainen 2002yf : H S R V L W W K D W & * 5 V Z L O O E H K L J K O \ U H V S R Q V L Y H W R W K H L U H I I H F W L Y H Q H V V L Q D F K L H Y L Q g desired impacts because cross-boundary engagement must generate "returns" for partners to justify their continued involvement to their own organizations and constituents. If initial joint action does not occur or the impacts are not close to the identified targets, CGRs will be pressured by their partners to make necessary adjustments in their targets, their theory of action, their collaborative dynamics, or their investments in building more capacity for joint action. If needed changes are not made, the low costs of exiting the regime will lead to low participation or departure. In theory, such adaptations should be more fea- sible in horizontal structures such as CGRs because the regime is more flexible, voluntary, and "soft- wired" compared to more structured, unitary organizations with stronger incentives to maintain status quo strategies and investment of resources. Integrating these adaptive feedback loops into our framework provides an orienting space for the study of adaptation within both the system context and CGRs themselves.7 Proposition Ten : CGRs will be more sustainable over time when they adapt to the nature and level of impacts resulting from their joint actions. DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSION A review of the integrative framework for collaborative governance and the resulting propositions is in order. These propositions are a first cut at describing the causal mechanisms that link the components and elements of the nested dimensions in the framework; they are presented as preliminary working assumptions in need of future testing and validation. 7 Changing conditions in the system context and the collaboration itself also occur for reasons other than in response to the impacts of CGRs. This framework is focused, however, on the resulting from regime impacts. This content downloaded from 128.6.45.205 on Thu, 26 Aug 2021 02:44:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 20 Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory We assert that collaborative governance unfolds within a system context that consists of a host of political, legal, socioeconomic, environmental, and other influences. This system context creates opportunities and constraints, and influences the dynamics and performance of collaboration at the outset and over time. Emerging from this system context are drivers , including leadership, consequential incentives, interdependence, and uncertainty. These drivers generate the energy for the initiation of a CGR and set its initial direction. We propose that one or more of these four drivers must be present to start a CGR and that the presence of more drivers increases the likelihood that such a regime will be initiated (Proposition 1yf . Once a CGR has been initiated, collaborative dynamics and its three components are set in motion. The first component, principled engagement , encompasses the interaction of four basic process elements: discovery, definition, deliberation, and determination. We posit that the principled engagement is generated and sustained by these four elements and that quality and effectiveness of principled engagement will depend on the nature of the interaction among these four elements over time (Proposition 2yf 7 K H V H F R Q d component, shared motivation , also consists of four elements: trust, mutual understanding, internal legitimacy, and shared commitment. We posit that principled engagement fosters these four elements, thus generating and sustaining shared motivation (Proposition 3yf . Moreover, we argue that once generated, shared motivation will further enhance and sustain principled engagement and vice versa in a "virtuous cycle" (Proposition 4yf . The third component of collaborative dynamics is the generation of capacity for joint action , which is also a function of four elements: procedural and institutional arrangements, leadership, knowledge, and resources. We posit that principled engagement and shared motivation assist with the development of these elements, thus generating and sustaining capacity for joint action (Proposition 5yf 0 R U H R Y H U Z H V X J J H V W W K D W W K H Q H F H V V D U \ O H Y H O V R f each element will vary based on the CGR' s purpose, shared theory of action, and targeted outcomes (Proposition 6yf ) L Q D O O \ Z L W K U H J D U G W R F R O O D E R U D W L Y H G \ Q D P L F V R X U V X P P D W L Y e proposition asserts that the quality and extent of these dynamics depends on the nature of the self-reinforcing interactions among principled engagement, shared motivation, and the capacity for joint action (Proposition 7yf . The components of collaborative dynamics (principled engagement, shared motivation, and capacity for joint actionyf L Q W H U D F W R Y H U W L P H V \ Q H U J L V W L F D O O \ D Q G S U R S H l collaborative action by the CGR. We posit that collaborative actions are more likely to be implemented if they are in line with an articulated shared theory of action and supported by the necessary capacity for joint action (Proposition 8yf : H D O V R S U R S R V H W K D W W K H U H V X O W L Q g impacts from collaborative action are likely to be closer to those intended and targeted by the regime with fewer unintended negative consequences if they have been specified in a shared theory of action developed through collaborative dynamics (Proposition 9yf . Finally, the potential for adaptation exists both within the system context and the CGR itself. We suggest that CGRs will be more sustainable over time when they adapt to the nature and level of impacts resulting from their joint actions (Proposition 10yf . We recognize that this integrative framework covers a lot of ground. It incorporates concepts from a wide range of literature and broadens the scope of collaborative governance beyond previous constructs. The framework identifies several general sets of variables (i.e., dimensions, components, and elementsyf D V Z H O O D V W K H U H O D W L R Q V K L S s among those variables, that will be of interest to scholars and practitioners of collaborative This content downloaded from 128.6.45.205 on Thu, 26 Aug 2021 02:44:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Emerson et al. Integrative Framework for Collaborative Governance 21 governance. In addition, derived from the framework are several propositions that both integrate existing theory and seek to build new theory about how the variables of collaborative governance interact to shape events and outcomes. Although the breadth of the framework is a strength, it also makes it difficult to adequately describe within the bounds of this article. By developing a framework that encompasses the context, driv- ers, engagement processes, motivational attributes, and joint capacities that enable shared decision making, management, implementation, and other activities across organizations, jurisdictions, and sectors, we have limited the space available to cover in depth the elements of each component and develop the full suite of causal pathways proposed. Nevertheless, the framework itself improves upon existing frameworks for collaborative governance in several ways. First, it examines collaborative governance broadly and treats it as an emergent system, a new kind of regime for cross-boundary governance. In doing so, it encompasses a wider range of collaborative initiatives than other definitions and extends beyond the typical focus on the public sector and the public manager to include the myriad of collaboratives initiated in the public, private, and civic sectors. Second, the framework specifies the components of the CGR in a way that integrates a range of factors identified in research into an operational system and suggests some general and very specific causal linkages. Although several frameworks acknowledge the iterative and dynamic nature of collaboration, this framework more explicitly builds that vibrant nature into its construction. Third, the framework also situates the CGR in the broader context with which it interacts. The regime is influenced by surrounding conditions and initiated by specific drivers, and the regime produces impacts affecting those surrounding conditions, as well as the regime itself and its collaborative dynamics. Finally, the framework goes beyond others in distinguishing actions from impacts and tracing the potential for adaptation of the system context and the CGR itself. The framework also provides a wealth of opportunities for future empirical research. At the most basic level, the generic nature of the framework should enable comparative analyses of CGRs across different system contexts and policy arenas. The depth of the framework, from the dimensions to individual elements, lends itself to thick description in individual or comparative case studies. The breadth of the framework enables efforts to gather more consistent data on a range of indicators from a large set of cases to test the propositions or specific hypotheses relating to the components, their elements, and their interactions. More specifically, there are numerous research opportunities at the framework, theory, and model levels articulated by Ostrom (2005yf ) L U V W W K H I U D P H Z R U N L W V H O I Z R X O G E H Q H I L t from critical applications to cases and examples of collaborative governance. It would be useful to closely examine the components and their interrelationships to describe their strengths and weaknesses, limits of applicability, areas where we have the most and least empirical evidence, and the potential role of various disciplines in contributing to pieces of the framework. Doing so could help identify the pieces of the framework that have the most empirical or practical support, as opposed to the pieces that are, at this point, more speculative. In turn, such research could help confirm or adjust the more speculative pieces. Moreover, we believe that the integrative framework can be applied usefully at different scales, in diverse policy arenas, and various levels of complexity. Future research can examine these assumptions, for example, by exploring how certain pieces of the framework apply in different settings such as community policing, environmental issues, or social This content downloaded from 128.6.45.205 on Thu, 26 Aug 2021 02:44:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 22 Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory services. Typologies of different kinds of CGRs can be envisioned, which in turn can generate future empirical analyses of the framework overall or of the interactions among different components and elements. Second, several theory testing possibilities exist. The propositions derived from the framework begin to build a general predictive theory for collaborative governance through an instrumental systems approach, as opposed to a prescriptive theory based on normative assumptions. As noted before, these working assumptions need to be tested and validated or revised. Moreover, although the framework encompasses many interactive components and elements, we do not mean to suggest that all are necessary all the time or at the same level of quality or to the same extent. Additional research is needed to discover which relationships matter in what contexts, that is, researchers need to identify where, when, and why which components are necessary, and to what degree, for collaborative success. For instance, in studying the four specified drivers, one might test which are most important. Our preliminary thought on this is that leadership is an essential driver, without which collab- orative regimes would not be initiated. However, without at least one or some combination of the other drivers (consequential incentives, interdependence, and/or uncertaintyyf D & * R is unlikely to continue. Likewise, scholars could examine which element or elements in each of the components of collaborative dynamics (principled engagement, shared motivation, and capacity for joint actionyf D U H H V V H Q W L D O I R U F R O O D E R U D W L Y H V X F F H V V , Q D V L P L O D r research direction, some of the coauthors are currently working on the relationship between collaborative capacity and adaptation, addressing how collaborative capacity might generate specific adaptive capacity and enhance adaptive action in CGRs addressing natural resource issues. More work is also needed to identify and explain the causal mechanisms that drive collaborative initiatives. Future research will be helpful in clarifying how the different components and elements in the framework emerge and how they relate to one another. For example, the drivers identified in the framework explain why collaboration might emerge but do not yet explain how specific drivers might affect the nature of the CGR differently or if and how the drivers continue to sustain the CGR as it evolves over time. Likewise, future research can explore the critical factors that influence the sustainability of CGRs. For example, one might examine what many have proposed in the literature that small initial successes (low hanging fruityf D U H H V V H Q W L D O W R N H H S D & * 5 J R L Q J L Q W K H L W V H D U O y stages (or that such successes are not sufficient in the long runyf 7 K L V Z R X O G U H T X L U H G H I L Q L Q g different levels of success (e.g., initial development of joint capacity for action, different kinds of actions, actions plus impacts, and so forthyf D V Z H O O D V W U D F N L Q J W K H O R Q J H Y L W \ R I W K e CGR, holding other components and elements constant. Finally, researchers can develop and test specific models and hypotheses relating to the components, their elements, and their interactions. For example, table 1 suggests a way in which to view the integrative framework as a logic model that can be used to test in- termediate outputs (actionsyf D Q G H Q G R X W F R P H V L P S D F W V D Q G D G D S W D W L R Q \f and become the basis for case evaluation and performance evaluation for program management (Thomas and Koontz, 201 1yf 6 L P L O D U O \ R W K H U P X O W L O H Y H O P R G H O L Q J P H W K R G R O R J L H V P D \ E H H P S O R \ H d to test more rigorously the contributions of several interrelated factors to specified out- comes (Arnold 1992; Emerson et al. 2009; O'Connell and McCoach 2004yf ) R U V X F K H Y D O - uation to begin, however, additional research is needed to operationalize the components This content downloaded from 128.6.45.205 on Thu, 26 Aug 2021 02:44:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Emerson et al. Integrative Framework for Collaborative Governance 23 and elements so that they can be tested. Work to develop indicators and measures for the dimensions, components, and elements in the integrative framework is currently underway. In terms of practice, the framework offers public managers and collaboration and conflict resolution practitioners a conceptual map by which to navigate the various dimensions, components, and elements of collaborative governance. The set of drivers provide useful considerations for deciding whether and when to invest in a CGR. Making the collaborative dynamics dimension explicit with participants at the outset can assist with the codesign of the most effective and appropriate CGR. Drawing attention to the elements within principled engagement, shared motivation, and the capacity for joint action can stimulate a shared perspective on needed strategic directions and on progress made to date. Working to articulate the targeted outcomes and coproduce a shared theory of action to affect those outcomes and the criteria by which to assess effective outcomes can enable participants to sharpen their sights and their pencils. Finally, understanding that a CGR is likely, if not expected, to adapt over time further enables the development of innovative learning systems for government and reflective practice (Argyris and Schon 1974; Schon 1971yf . There can be little argument that the notion of collaborative governance is attracting considerable attention as a new paradigm in public administration. It is the subject of a growing number of books, articles, and monographs. It is seen by many as the new way of doing the business of government. Despite the popularity of the term in research, and claims of its wide-spread use in practice, the study of collaborative governance continues to suffer from a lack of conceptual clarity and consistency. In this article, we have sought to address this by developing an integrative framework that we hope will engender improvements in the theory, research, evaluation, and practice of collaborative governance. FUNDING Morris K. and Stewart L. Udall Foundation; Syracuse University; the State University of New York - College of Environmental Science and Forestry. REFERENCES Agranoff, Robert. 2006. Inside collaborative networks: Ten lessons for public managers. Public Administration Review 66:56-65. Collaborative Public Management , eds. L. B. Bingham and R. O'Leary, 162-94. Armonk, NY : M.E. Sharpe. Agranott, Robert, and Michael McGuire. 1998. Multinetwork management: Collaboration and the hollow state in local economic policy. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 8:67-91. Review 61:671-81. Agrawal, Arun, and Maria Carmen Lemos. 2007. A Greener revolution in the making? Environmental governance in the 21st century. Environment 49:36-45. Ansell, Chris, and Alison Gash. 2008. Collaborative governance in theory and practice. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 18:543-71. This content downloaded from 128.6.45.205 on Thu, 26 Aug 2021 02:44:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 24 Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory Argyris, Chris, and Donald A. Schon. 1974. Theory in practice: Increasing professional effectiveness. Oxford, England: Jossey-Bass. Arnold, Carolyn L. 1992. Methods, plainly speaking: An introduction to hierarchical linear modeling. Measurement and Education in Counseling and Development 25:58-88. Axelrod, Robert. 1984. The evolution of cooperation. New York, NY: Basic Books. Bandura, Albert. 1977. Social learning theory. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall. Bardach, Eugene. 1998. Getting agencies to work together. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution. Public Administration Research and Theory 11:149-64. Beierle, Thomas A., and Jerry Cayford. 2002. Democracy in practice. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future. Bentley, Arthur. 1949. The process of government. Evanston, IL: Principia Press. Bentrup, Gary. 2001. Evaluation of a collaborative mode: A case study analysis of watershed planning in the intermountain west. Environmental Management 27:739-48. Berry, Carolyn A., Glen S. Krutz, Barbara E. Langner, and Peter Budetti. 2008. Jump-starting collaboration: The ABCD initiative and the provision of child development services through medicaid and collaborators. Public Administration Review 68:480-90. Bingham, Lisa Blomgren and Rosemary O'Leary, eds. 2008. Big ideas in collaborative public management. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe. Bingham, Lisa Blomgren. 2008. Legal frameworks for collaboration in governance and public management. In Big ideas in collaborative public management , eds. L. B. Bingham and R. O'Leary, 247-69. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe. Journal on Dispute Resolution 24: 1-5 1 . Bloomfield, Pamela. 2006. The challenging business of long-term public-private partnerships: Reflections on local experience. Public Administration Review 66:400-11. Borrini-Feyerabend, Grazia. 1996. Collaborative management of protected areas: Tailoring the approach to the context. Gland, Switzerland: IUCN. Brown, Trevor, Matthew Potoski, and David M. Van Slyke. 2007. Managing public service contracts: Aligning values, institutions and markets. Public Administration Review 66:323-31. Bryson, John M., and Barbara C. Crosby. 2008. Failing into cross-sector collaboration successfully. In Big ideas in collaborative public management , eds. L. B. Bingham and R. O'Leary, 55-78. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe. Bryson, John M., Barbara C. Crosby, and Melissa Middleton Stone. 2006. The design and implementation of cross-sector collaborations: Propositions form the literature. Public Administration Review 66:44-55. Cahn, Dudley D., ed. 1994. Conflict in personal relationships. Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates. Carlson, Christine. 2007. A practical guide to collaborative governance. Portland, OR: Policy Consensus Initiative. Carpenter, Susan L., and W. J. D. Kennedy. 2001. Managing public disputes: A practical guide for government, business, and citizen 's groups. San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass. Colman, James S. 1988. Social capital in the creation of human capital. American Journal of Sociology 94:95-120. Conley, Alexander, and Margaret A. Moote. 2003. Evaluating collaborative natural resource management. Society and Natural Resources 16:371-86. Terry, L., Thomas A. Bryer, and Jack W. Meek. 2006. Citizen-centered collaborative public management. Public Administration Review 66:76-88. Crosby, Barbara C., and John M. Bryson. 2005. Leadership for the common good : Tackling public problems in a shared-power world. San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass. Cross, Rob, and Andrew Parker. 2004. The hidden power of social networks. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press. This content downloaded from 128.6.45.205 on Thu, 26 Aug 2021 02:44:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Emerson et al. Integrative Framework for Collaborative Governance 25 Cupach, William R., and Daniel J. Canary. 1997. Competence in interpersonal conflict. New York: McGraw-Hill. Daley, Dorothy M. 2009. Interdisciplinary problems and agency boundaries: exploring effective cross- agency collaboration. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 19:477-93. Daniels, Steven E., and Gregg Walker. 2001. Working through environmental conflict: The collaborative approach. Westport, CT: Praeger. Dawes, Robyn M. 1973. The commons dilemma game: An /V-person mixed-motive game with a dominating strategy for defection. ORI Research Bulletin 13:1-12. Donahue, John. 2004. On collaborative governance. Working Paper #2. CSRI. http://www.hks. harvard. edu/m-rcbg/C SRI/publications/workingpaper_2_donahue .pdf. Dudley, Larkin, and Mary Raymer. 2001. Inside organizational change: Puzzling across permeable boundaries. Public Administration Review 61:620-24. Dukes, E. Franklin. 2004. What we know about environmental conflict resolution: An analysis based on research. Conflict Resolution Quarterly 22:191- 220. Durant, Robert F., Young-Pyoung Chun, Byungseob Kim, and Seongjong Lee. 2004. Toward a new governance paradigm for environmental and natural resources management in the 21st century? Administration & Society 35:643-82. Ebrahim, Alnoor. 2004. Institutional preconditions to collaboration: Indian forest and irrigation policy in historical perspective. Administration & Society 36:208-42. Ehrmann, John R., and Barbara Stinson. 1999. Joint fact-finding and the use of technical experts. In The consensus building handbook: A comprehensive guide to reaching agreement , eds. L. Susskind, S. McKearnan, and J. Thomas-Larmer, 375-99. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. Elazar, Daniel J. 1962. The American partnership: Intergovernmental cooperation in the nineteenth century United States. Chicago, IL: Univ. of Chicago Press. Emerson, Kirk, and Peter Murchie. 2010. Collaborative governance and climate change: Opportunities for public administration. In The future of public administration, public management , and public service around the world : The Minnowbrook perspective , eds. R. O'Leary, D. Van Slyke, and S. Kim, 141-53. Washington, DC: Georgetown Univ. Emerson, Kirk, Tina Nabatchi, Rosemary O'Leary, and John Stephens. 2003. The challenges of environmental conflict resolution. In The promise and performance for environmental conflict resolution , eds. R. O'Leary and L. B. Bingham, 3-26. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future. Emerson, Kirk, Patricia J. Orr, Dale L. Keyes, and Katherine M. McKnight. 2009. Environmental conflict resolution: Evaluating performance outcomes and contributing factors. Conflict Resolution Quarterly 27:27-64. Farazamand, Ali. 2007. Learning from the Katrina crisis: A global and international perspective with implications for future crisis management. Public Administration Review 67:149-59. Fisher, Robert, William Ury, and Bruce Patton. 1991. Getting to yes, 2nd ed. New York, NY: Penguin Books. Fisher, Roger, and Scott Brown. 1989. Getting together: Building relationships as we negotiate. New York, NY: Penguin Books. Fishkin, James S. 1991 . Democracy and deliberation: New directions for democratic reform. New Haven, CT: Yale Univ. Press. Frederickson, H. George. 1991 . Toward a theory of the public for public administration. Administration & Society 22:395-417. Fung, Archon. 2006. Varieties of participation in complex governance. Public Administration Review 66:66-75. Fung, Archon, and Erik O. Wright. 2001. Deepening democracy: Institutional innovations in empowered participatory governance. New York, NY: Verso. Goldberg, Stephen В., Frank E. A. Sanders, and Nancy H. Rogers, eds. 1992. Dispute resolution, negotiation, mediation and other processes , 2nd ed. New York, NY: Aspen Law and Business. Graddy, Elizabeth A., and Bin Chen. 2006. Influences on the size and scope of networks for social service delivery. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 16:533-52. This content downloaded from 128.6.45.205 on Thu, 26 Aug 2021 02:44:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 26 Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory Gray, Barbara. 1989. Collaborating: Finding common ground for multiparty problems. San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass. Groff, Todd R., and Thomas P. Jones. 2003. Introduction to knowledge management: KM in business. Burlington, MA: Elsevier Science. Heikkila, Tanya, and Andrea K. Gerlak. 2005. The formation of large-scale collaborative resource management institutions: Clarifying the roles of stakeholders, science, and institutions. Policy Studies Journal 33:583-612. Henton, Doug, John Melville, Terry Amsler, and Malka Kopell. 2005. Collaborative governance: A guide for grantmakers. Menlo Park, CA: William and Flora Hewlett Foundation. Himmelman, Arthur T. 1994. Communities working collaboratively for change. In Resolving conflict: Strategies for local government , ed. M. S. Herrman, 21-M. Washington, DC: International City/ County Management Association. Holling, Crawford Stanley. 1978. Adaptive environmental assessment and management. New York, NY: John Wiley & Sons. Huxham, Chris. 2003. Theorizing collaboration practice. Public Management Review 5:401-23. Huxham, Chris, S. Vangen, C. Huxham, and C. Eden. 2000. The challenge of collaborative governance. Public Management Review 2:337-58. Huxham, Chris, and Siv Vangen. 2005. Managing to collaborate : The theory and practice of collaborative advantage. New York, NY: Routledge. Imperial, Mark. 2005. Using collaboration as a governance strategy: Lessons from six watershed management programs. Administration & Society 37:281-320. Innes, Judith E., and David E. Booher. 1999. Consensus building and complex adaptive systems: A framework for evaluating collaborative planning. Journal of the American Planning Association 65:412-23. Jenkins, William O. 2006. Collaboration over adaptation: The case for interoperable communications in homeland security. Public Administration Review 66:319-21. Jun, J. S., ed. 2002. Rethinking administrative theory: The challenge of the new century. Westport, CT: Praeger. Kamensky, John M., and Thomas J. Burlin. 2004. Collaboration: Using networks and partnerships. Lanham, MD: Rowman and Littlefield. Karkkainen, Bradley C. 2002. Collaborative ecosystem governance: Scale, complexity, and dynamism. Virginia Environmental Law Journal 21:189-243. Kettl, Donald F. 2002. The transformation of governance: Public administration for twenty-first century America. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press. Administration Review 66:10-19. Koontz, Tomas M., and Craig W. Thomas. 2006. What do we know and need to know about the environmental outcomes of collaborative management? Public Administration Review 66:111-21. Koontz, Tomas M., Toddi A. Steelman, JoAnn Carmin, Katrina Smith Kormacher, Cassandra Moseley, and Craig W. Thomas. 2004. Collaborative environmental management: What roles for government? Washington, DC: Resources for the Future Press. Koppenjan, Joop, and Erik-Hans Klijn. 2004. Managing uncertainty in networks : A network approach to problem solving and decision making. New York, NY: Routledge. Korfmacher, Katrina S. 2000. Partnering for ecosystem management of the Darby Creek watershed. American Behavioral Scientist 22:548-64. Krasner, Stephen D. 1983. Structural causes and regime consequences: Regimes as intervening variables. In International regimes , ed. S. D. Krasner, 1-22. Ithaca, NY: Cornell Univ. Press. Kumar, Sushil, Shashi Kant, and Terry L. Amburgey. 2007. Public agencies and collaborative management approaches: Examining resistance among administrative professionals. Administration & Society 39:569-610. Leach, William D. 2006. Collaborative public management and democracy: Evidence from Western watershed partnerships. Public Administration Review 66:100-10. This content downloaded from 128.6.45.205 on Thu, 26 Aug 2021 02:44:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Emerson et al. Integrative Framework for Collaborative Governance 27 Leach, William D., and Neil W. Pelkey. 2001. Making watershed partnerships work: A review of the empirical literature. Journal of Water Resources Planning and Management 127:378-85. Leach, William D., and Paul A. Sabatier. 2005. To trust an adversary: Integrating rational and psy- chological models of collaborative policy making. American Political Science Review 99:491-503. Lubell, Mark, William D. Leach, and Paul A. Sabatier. 2009. Collaborative watershed partnerships in the epoch of sustainability. In Toward sustainable communities transition and transformations in environmental policy , eds. D. A. Mazmanian and M. E. Kraft, 255-88. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Lulofs, Roxane S., and Dudley D. Cahn. 2000. Conflict : From theory to action. Boston, MA: Allyn and Bacon. Manring, Nancy J. 2005. The politics of accountability in national forest planning. Administration & Society 37:57-88. McGuire, Michael. 2006. Collaborative public management: Assessing what we know and how we know it. Public Administration Review 66:33-43. Milward, H. Brinton, and Keith G. Provan. 2000. How networks are governed. In Governance and performance: New perspectives , eds. C. J. Heinrich and L. E. Lynn, 238-62. Washington, DC: Georgetown Press. Center for the Business of Government. Nabatchi, Tina. 2010. Addressing the citizenship and democratic deficits: Exploring the potential of deliberative democracy for public administration. American Review of Public Administration 40:376-99. National Research Council. 2009. Informing decisions in a changing climate, panel on strategies and methods for climate-related decision support, committee on the human dimensions of global change. Division of behavioral and social sciences and education. Washington, DC: National Academies Press. Nicholson-Crotty, Sean, and Laurence O'Toole. 2004. Public management and organizational performance: The case of law enforcement agencies. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 14:1-18. O'Connell, A. A., and D. B. McCoach. 2004. Applications of hierarchical linear modeling for evaluations of health interventions: Demystifying the methods and interpretations of multi-level models. Evaluation in the Health Professions 27:119-51. O'Leary, Rosemary, and Lisa Blomgren Bingham. 2003. The promise and performance of environmental conflict resolution. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future. O'Leary, Rosemary, Lisa Blomgren Bingham, and Catherine Gerard. 2006. Special issue on collaborative public management. Public Administration Review 66:1-170. Olsen, Mancur. 1965. The logic of collective action: Public goods and the theory of groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Univ. Press. Ostrom, Elinor. 1990. Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge: Cambridge Univ. Press. Science Review 92:1-22. Sciences 104:15181-7. Ozawa, Connie. 1991. Recasting science: Consensual procedures in public policy making. Boulder, CO: Westview Press. Page, Stephen. 2003. Entrepreneurial strategies for managing interagency collaboration. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 13:311-39. Pahl-Wostl, Claudia. 2007. Transitions toward adaptive management of water facing climate and global change. Water Resources Management 21:49-62. Pressman, Jeffrey L., and Aaron Wildavsky. 1973. Implementation. Berkeley, CA: Univ. of California Press. This content downloaded from 128.6.45.205 on Thu, 26 Aug 2021 02:44:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 28 Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory Prován, Keith G., and H. Brinton Milward. 1995. A preliminary theory of interorganizational effec- tiveness: A comparative study of four community mental health systems. Administrative Science Quarterly 40:1-33. Putnam, Robert. 1995. Bowling alone: America's declining social capital. Journal of Democracy 6:65-78. Schuster. Putnam, Robert, Robert Leonardi, and Raffaella Y. Nanetti. 1993. Making democracy work : Civic traditions in modern Italy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univ. Press. Rabe, Barry, ed. 2010. Greenhouse governance: Addressing climate change in America. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution. Radin, Beryl A. 1996. Managing across boundaries. In The state of public management , eds. D. F. Kettl and H. B. Milward, 145-67. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins Univ. Press. Raiffa, Howard. 1982. The art and science of negotiation. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Univ. Press. Ring, Peter Smith., and Andrew H. Van de Ven. 1994. Developmental processes of cooperative inter- organizational relationships. Academy of Management Review 19:90-118. Rittel, Horst, and Melvin Webber. 1973. Dilemmas in a general theory of planning. Policy Sciences 4:155-69. Roberts, Nancy. 2004. Public deliberation in the age of direct citizen participation. American Review of Public Administration 34:315-53. Romzek, Barbara S., and Jocelyn M. Johnston. 2005. State social services contracting: Exploring the determinants of effective contract accountability. Public Administration Review 65:436-49. Sabatier, Paul A., Will Focht, Mark Lubell, Zev Trachtenberg, Arnold Vedlitz, and Marty Matlock, eds. 2005. Swimming upstream, collaborative approaches to watershed management. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Saint-Onge, Hubert, and Charles Armstrong. 2004. The conductive organization building beyond sus- tainability. New York, NY: Elsevier. Schneider, Mark, John Scholz, Mark Lubell, Denisa Mindruta, and Matthew Edwardsen. 2003. Building consensual institutions: Networks and the National Estuary Program. American Journal of Political Science 47:143-58. Schlager, Edella, and William A. Blomquist. 2008. Embracing watershed politics. Boulder, CO: Univ. Press of Colorado. Schon, Donai A. 1971. Beyond the stable state. New York: W.W. Norton Company. Selin, S., and D. Chavez. 1995. Developing a collaborative model for environmental planning and management. Environmental Management 19:189-95. Sipe, Neil G., and Bruce Stiftel. 1995. Mediating environmental enforcement disputes: How well does it work? Environmental Impact Assessment Review 15:139-56. Sirianni, Carmen. 2009. Investing in democracy engaging citizens in collaborative governance. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution. Skocpol, Theda. 2002. Diminished democracy: From membership to management in American civic life. Norman, OK: Univ. of Oklahoma Press. Smith, Craig R. 2009. Institutional determinants of collaboration: An empirical study of county open- space protection. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 19:1-21. Steelman, Toddi A., and JoAnn Carmin. 2002. Community based watershed remediation: Connecting organization resources to social and substantive outcomes. In Toxic waste and environmental policy in the 21st century United States , ed. D. Rahm, 145-78. Jefferson, NC: McFarland. Sowa, Jessica E. 2008. Implementing interagency collaborations: Exploring variation in collaborative ventures in human service organizations. Administration & Society 40:298-323. Susskind, Larry, Sarah McKearnan, and Jennifer Thomas-Larmer, eds. 1999. The consensus-building handbook : A comprehensive guide to reaching agreement. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Books. Susskind, Lawrence, and Jeffrey Cruikshank. 1987. Breaking the impasse: Consensual approaches to resolving public disputes. New York: Basic Books. Taylor, Heather-Getha. 2006. Preparing leaders for high-stakes collaborative action: Darrell Darnel and the Department of Homeland Security. Public Administration Review 66:159-60. This content downloaded from 128.6.45.205 on Thu, 26 Aug 2021 02:44:32 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Emerson et al. Integrative Framework for Collaborative Governance 29 Thomas, Craig W., and Tomas M. Koontz. 2011. Research designs for examining the impact of com- munity-based management on natural resource conservation. Journal of Natural Resources Policy Research 3:97-111. Thomson, Ann Marie., and James Perry. 2006. Collaboration processes: Inside the black box. Public Administration Review 66:20-32. Torres, Lars H. 2003. Deliberative democracy: A survey of the field in a report prepared for the William and Flora Hewlett Foundation . Washington, DC: AmericaSpeaks. Wood, Donna, and Barbara Gray. 1991. Toward a comprehensive theory of collaboration. Journal of Applied Behavioral Science 27:139-62. Wright, Deil S. 1988. Understanding intergovernmental relations. Belmont, CA: Duxbury Press. This content downloaded from 128.6.45.205 on Thu, 26 Aug 2021 , 01 Jan 1976 12:34:56 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms