Latin America

The Limits of Democracy: Socio-Political Compromise and Regime Change in Post-Pinochet Chile Patrick s Barrett Introduction S ince the early 1980s, Latin America (and the developing world more generally) has undergone a historically significant transition from military to civilian rule. Like the authoritarianism that preceded it, the number and coincidence of these transitions have captured the interests of scholars, prompting a new inquiry into the causes of this most recent wave of regime changes and whether it represents a decisive movement toward democratic stability. Among the countries that have recently undergone the transition from authoritarian rule, Chile affords a particu- larly rich case study for addressing this question. Indeed, despite having suffered perhaps the most traumatic democratic collapse and undergone the most profound and far-reaching authoritarian transformation, its transition to civilian rule proved remarkably smooth and the regime that emerged from that process appears to be among the most stable of Latin America's new democracies. In fact, when a ma- jority of Chilean electors voted for the presidential candidate of the center-left Concertacidn de Partidos por la Democracia (CPPD) in December 1989, it was the first multiparty majority coalition to be elected in Chile since the early 1940s.

Furthermore, the CPPD's subsequent victory in 1993 marked the first time that an incumbent government had been reelected since 1946. For the first time in nearly half a century, moreover, there exists virtually no dispute over the country's devel- opment strategy, much less the system of capitalist development. And finally, per- haps the most noteworthy feature of Chile's new found political stability is the unexpectedly harmonious relations between the CPPD and Chile's business com- munity. In short, Chile is today enjoying a new socio-political compromise no less Patrick S. Barrett is the Administrative Director of the Havens Center for the Study of Social Structure and Social Change at the University of Wisconsin-Madison, where he also received a Ph.D. in Political Science.

His primary interests are in comparative and international political economy and democratization, with a regional specialization in Latin America. He is currently working on a book manuscript titled The Limits of Democracy: Socio-Political Compromise and Regime Change in Chile.

Address correspondence to: Depart- ment of Sociology, University of Wisconsin-Madison, 8117 Social Science, Madison, WI 53706. 4 Studies in Comparative International Development / Fall 1999 significant than the so-called estado de compromiso ("compromise state") of the 1930s and 1940s, the other moment in its history when it was regarded as the most stable and promising of Latin America's democracies. This remarkable turn of events raises three intriguing questions. First, what are the causes of Chile's new socio-political compromise? Second, what are the sub- stantive terms of this compromise; i.e., what tradeoffs underpin it and what ten- sions is it designed to resolve? Finally, what implications does this compromise have for the character and trajectory of the post-military order? Does it constitute the basis for continued democratic stability under post-military rule, or, like Chile's previous compromise, does it mask underlying political, social, and economic con- tradictions that bode ill for democratic stability? Clearly, this outcome has deep historical roots in Chile's prior experiences of socio-political compromise, democratic collapse, and authoritarian transforma- tion. The focus of this article, however, is the 199001997 period, during which Chile's new compromise has been consolidated. 1 Its central argument is that this compromise can best be understood as a reflection of, and an attempt to contain, the historical and ongoing tension between the imperative of capital accumulation and the conflicts over socio-political inclusion and distribution. More concretely, the article examines struggles over three arenas of conflict that reflect that tension most clearly: development strategy; labor and social policy; and the structure of state decision-making. Central to those conflicts, moreover, was the evolving rela- tionship between business, parties, and the state. Indeed, it is the limitations of that relationship, and more specifically the limitations on the state's capacity to disci- pline business, which constitute the limits of Chile's new socio-political compro- mise. The article concludes that this compromise can be characterized as a neo-liberal elite pact between big business and political party elites, which rather than reconciling accumulation and inclusion/distribution, has privileged the former over the latter. The article consists of six sections. Section I presents the analytical framework. Section II briefly examines the period of authoritarian transformation from 1973 to 1989, which established many of the institutional and structural conditions that shaped and constrained the processes of transition and compromise. Sections III through V examine the CPPD administrations of Patricio Aylwin and Eduardo Frei (1990-1997), focusing on the three central pillars of Chile's new compromise.

Finally, the conclusion briefly assesses the prospects for democratic stability in light of that compromise.

1. Analytical Framework 2 The central theoretical argument of this article is that all capitalist societies are characterized by a permanent tension between the imperative of capital accumula- tion and the conflicts over socio-political inclusion and distribution.

What distin- guishes those societies, both from one another and over time, is the capacity to contain this tension. The degree of democracy and political stability attained by a given society can therefore be understood as the product of whether and how this tension is contained. More specifically, it is the product of whether and how state strategic capacity is generated: i.e., the ability to adapt to changing domestic and Barrett 5 international circumstances by making timely shifts in development strategy con- ducive to a process of sustained capital accumulation. 3 Above all this means the capacity to discipline social classes, and private capital in particular. Indeed, it is whether and how that capacity is generated that determines the limits of democ- racy under capitalism. By assigning a central role in the accumulation process to the state, this argu- ment runs counter to much recent scholarship in the political economy of develop- ment. This is particularly true of the neo-orthodox perspective, which holds that rather than contributing to economic development, state intervention has been the principal cause of economic decline. This perspective, however, suffers from a number of analytical and historical shortcomings that have been amply discussed in the literature on development. 4 A second, more compelling, line of argument holds not that the state is the cause of economic decline, but rather that because of the changing structural character of the international economy (specifically, the enormous increase in the international mobility of capital and the globalization of production and trade), the state's capacity for effective intervention has been greatly diminished (Strange 1996). But while there is indeed evidence that these develop- ments have constrained national policy-making autonomy (particularly in the area of macroeconomic policy), 5 the state nonetheless remains central to economic development. In the first place, as Robert Wade (1996) has recently argued, reports of the death of the national economy have been greatly exaggerated, as world production and investment remain very largely nationally owned and oriented. 6 Moreover, the need to adapt to a changing international economy does not mean that all countries will adapt successfully or in the same way (Scharpf 1991; Zysman 1983). States differ in their endogenous structural capacity for strategic action, in the extent to which their existing economic structures can adapt to international conditions, and in their vulnerability to international trends and pressures (Cerny 1991). Perhaps the most important implication of today's changing international economy, how- ever, is not simply that it has made effective state intervention more difficult (which itself has increased the differences among states), but rather that it has made necessary a shift in the character of that intervention. More specifically, it has heightened the importance of supply-side, micro-economic forms of in- tervention, or a greater reliance on industrial and strategic trade policies. 7 This has always been true of late developers, but it is particularly so in light of the changing structure of international trade (most importantly, the growing trade in high value-added or "elaborately transformed" manufactures), which has eroded comparative advantages based on natural resources and cheap la- bor, while greatly enhancing the importance of technology acquisition and development, product specialization, and skills training. International com- petitiveness has, in other words, come to depend increasingly on the ability to construct "competitive" advantage by actively identifying and selecting particular sectors in which to encourage investment, facilitate access to technology, promote R&D and skills training, and develop new infrastructure. Where catching-up is the priority, simply "getting prices right" is no guarantee of growth; instead, it is likely to attain static comparative advantage and allocative efficiency at the price of sac- rificing dynamic comparative advantage and efficiency} Thus, rather than dimin- 6 Studies in Comparative International Development / Fall 1999 ishing the importance of effective state action, the changing international economy has, if anything, increased it. 9 As stated above, the key to state strategic capacity resides above all in the abil- ity to discipline social classes, but particularly the owners and corporate managers of capital, whose significance derives from their control over investment. ~~ In a capitalist economy, in other words, the satisfaction of business interests is a neces- sary condition for the satisfaction of all others. This means satisfying the condi- tions of profitability, which neither the state nor other social and political actors can undermine without risking losses in production, revenue, and employment and threatening the stability of the entire social and political order (Lindblom 1977; Block 1987). But while profitability is a necessary condition for accumulation, it is not sufficient. Sustained accumulation also requires that private profit-seeking be disciplined by the state, for there is no guarantee that the discipline of the mar- ket alone will lead capitalists to invest at high levels and in activities that are both productive and domestic. Moreover, even market discipline depends on the exist- ence of a state capable of enforcing it. Disciplining capital, however, is no easy achievement and indeed is fraught with tensions. This is particularly true of microeconomic forms of intervention, which constitute a potentially greater intru- sion upon business autonomy and prerogatives and carry greater risks of the rent- seeking decried by neo-orthodox scholars. Crucial to disciplining capital, then, is the ability to influence private investment decisions without either opening the door to predatory rent-seeking or triggering a defensive reaction in the form of a decline in investment and/or efforts aimed at restricting the scope of state action.

The state's ability to influence investment in this way, moreover, does not rest on a capacity to impose its policy objectives over the objections of an entire business class. The state may be able to do so temporarily, but certainly not in a sustained way and not without incurring serious economic problems.L1 The question then is under what conditions the generation of strategic capacity (and in particular, the discipline of capital) can be reconciled with democratization and under what conditions it cannot. In order to address this question, it is neces- sary to focus more closely on the tension between accumulation and inclusion/ distribution and whether and how it can be contained. The latter half of this equa- tion is most clearly reflected in labor and social policies and the structure of state decision-making. The importance of labor and social policies resides in the fact that they consti- tute important instruments for correcting the distributional inequalities generated by capitalist development, and as such represent important indicators of democra- tization. ~2 According to the neo-orthodox perspective, however, efforts to achieve equity through such policies pose an inherent threat to accumulation and economic efficiency. In the first instance, this is because redistributive measures reduce the profit share of income and thereby lower investment and growth. Moreover, labor standards are seen as a major source of labor market rigidity. Indeed, it is only by restricting union power, deregulating labor markets, and allowing wages to re- spond flexibly to market signals that full employment, stable prices, and growth will be achieved. State-provided social protection, moreover, should be made avail- able only to the certifiably destitute who are unable to participate in the labor market, while for those who are able to work, social protection should be provided Barrett 7 by privately organized insurance, with entitlements and benefits reflecting contri- butions. The impact of labor and social policies on accumulation and economic effi- ciency, however, is far more complex and varied than the neo-orthodox position suggests. In the first place, as Keynesians contend, wages are not only a cost of production, but also a source of demand and therefore a stimulus to profits and investment.13 Moreover, while it may be rational for labor to exercise wage re- straint in order to generate the profits upon which future growth and employment depend, private control of investment makes this risky for labor, for it has no guar- antee that the income it foregoes will be invested productively or that it will share in the resulting productivity gains. Furthermore, labor market flexibility is an in- sufficient basis for economic growth and may in fact be counterproductive, since enabling capital to continually squeeze labor can, on the demand side, limit the growth of the domestic market, and on the supply side, inhibit the switch to more productivity-enhancing business strategies. This is especially true in light of the changing structure of international trade, which has eroded comparative advan- tages based on cheap labor, while increasing the importance of technology acqui- sition and development, product specialization, and skills training. At the same time, there is no guarantee that raising labor standards and incomes will lead capital to invest in a manner that generates increased productivity. It may instead lead more quickly to a fall in profitability, capital flight, and/or heightened distributional conflict. Again, the effort to raise productivity will depend in sig- nificant measure on the state's capacity to discipline private investment decisions.

Moreover, the changes in the global economy have increased the importance of microeconomic forms of discipline. But this raises a fundamental problem: it is here that a workable compromise between capital and labor is most difficult to achieve. In other words, the state's ability to discipline capital on a microeconomic level through selective intervention may entail the exclusion of labor, for capital's reticence toward such discipline is likely to be considerably greater if labor has any say in it. 14 This is especially true if labor is strong or there is already a consid- erable history of high labor-capital conflict. This brings us to the relationship between state strategic capacity and inclusion. A central assertion of this article is that a primary (though not exclusive) motiva- tion for engaging in political struggle is to affect how the state intervenes in socio- economic conditions and relations (most importantly, the creation and distribution of wealth). But deciding how the state intervenes is not open to all social and political forces equally, because the state's forms of representation are typically structured in such a way as to privilege or "select" certain social and political actors over others. Similarly, the state's forms of intervention are also typically structured in a manner that privileges the policy preferences of certain actors over those of others (Jessop 1990). At the heart of the struggle over how the state inter- venes, then, is the struggle over both the accessibility and the scope of state deci- sion-making. In the neo-orthodox view, a state decision-making apparatus that is broad in scope and accessible to the electorate poses a potentially serious threat to accumu- lation and sound economic policy-making. This is because it encourages voters and pressure groups to make unrestrained demands on politicians who are only too 8 Studies in Comparative International Development / Fall 1999 willing to satisfy them in order to attain and retain elective office, thus opening the door to uncontrolled rent-seeking and an ever expanding politicization of social and economic relations. The neo-orthodox solution to the problem, therefore, lies in restricting both the accessibility and the scope of state decision-making in order to insulate the economy and economic policy-making from the distorting effects of politics. ~5 However, the relationship between accumulation and inclusion, like that between accumulation and distribution, is more complex and varied than the stark choice painted by neo-orthodoxy. To be sure, a decision-making apparatus that is broad in scope and/or highly accessible may generate excessive politicization and rent-seeking. But the price for preventing such an outcome will be restrictions not only on democratic representation, but also on the state's capacity to foster accumulation. Hence, while a restricted decision-making apparatus may generate stability at time t, it may be the cause of instability at time t+l because of the state's inability to accommodate rising demands for expanded popular representa- tion and/or respond to changing economic conditions. Furthermore, a decision- making apparatus that is broad in scope or highly accessible is also clearly compatible with sound economic policy-making and sustained accumulation. ~6 The degree of compatibility depends not only on the particular combination of institutional factors, but also on the nature of the accumulation strategy. For ex- ample, a Keynesian-inspired strategy is compatible with an accessible decision- making arena, but the scope of that arena will likely be primarily limited to macroeconomic policies. Conversely, an industrial policy strategy will involve a broader scope of state decision-making (encompassing both macro- and microeconomic policies), but its accessibility will likely be considerably more restricted. Finally, a neo-liberal strategy will involve greater restrictions, not only on the scope of state decision-making, but very likely on its accessibility as well. To summarize, the central theoretical contention of this article is that the princi- pal driving force behind the historical process of regime change is the struggle to contain the tension between the imperative of sustained accumulation and the con- flicts over socio-political inclusion and distribution. The degree of democracy and political stability attained by a given society can therefore be understood as a product of not only whether, but how, this tension is contained. More specifically, it is a product of whether and how the state succeeds in disciplining social classes, and private capital in particular, i.e., in a manner that reconciles accumulation and inclusion/distribution, privileges one over the other, or fails altogether. It is in this way that Chile's new socio-political compromise should be understood and it is to an analysis of that compromise that we now turn.

II. Authoritarian Transformation and Transition: The Institutional and Structural Foundations of Compromise In a remarkably striking way, the transformative project undertaken by the Chil- ean military regime in the mid-1970s reflected the fundamental tension between accumulation and inclusion/distribution that lay at the heart of democratic com- promise, stalemate, and collapse between 1932 and 1973. The basic pillars of that project were: (1) a neo-liberal development strategy that transformed the Chilean economy from one built on state-led ISI to one founded on primary product ex- Barrett 9 ports, rapid integration into the world economy, and a drastically reduced role for the state; (2) labor and social policies that sacrificed distribution to accumulation and sought to depoliticize social relations by reorienting them on the basis of mar- ket principles; and (3) a highly restrictive constitution designed to prevent the type of politicization seen to have undermined the previous civilian regime and to insti- tutionalize the regime's socio-economic model. Finally, the regime's transforma- tive project came to be explicitly linked to the construction of a post-military (though not necessarily post-authoritarian) order, complete with elaborate transition mecha- nisms. By 1981, the regime's transformative project appeared on its way to consolida- tion. The following year, however, the economic model collapsed, triggering the most severe economic crisis experienced by any of Latin America's authoritarian regimes. Yet, despite the explosion of mass protests and the reemergence of a po- litical opposition, the regime was able to survive, owing to many of the same factors that made the implementation of its transformative project possible (most importantly, the concentration of institutional and coercive power in the hands of General Augusto Pinochet, the strong backing from big business, and the divisions among and within the parties of the opposition as well as the right). This in turn enabled the regime to maintain its transition timetable and to embark on a second, more solid phase of authoritarian transformation during the latter half of the 1980s. Indeed, within the relatively short span of five years, dramatic changes occurred, which not only made possible Latin America's most orderly and consensual transition to civilian rule, but more importantly laid the foundations for the construction of Chile's second socio-political compromise during this century. What is particularly significant about this period is the way in which institu- tional and structural factors interacted in constraining and shaping the processes of transition and compromise. The most important institutional factors at play dur- ing this period were Pinochet's undiminished control over the state apparatus and the Armed Forces, the ongoing divisions among and within the parties of the oppo- sition and the right, and the existence of a set of transition procedures and an institutional design for the future already in place to which the military had tied its own institutional interests. This combination of institutional factors gave the re- gime the strategic upper hand and frustrated the opposition's efforts to force an early transition to a more open and democratic regime. Yet, paradoxically, the regime's very strength and determination to defend the Constitution and its transi- tion procedures eventually had the unintended effect of uniting the opposition. For by giving it no other choice but to participate in the October 1988 plebiscite over Pinochet's continuation as president, the regime enabled the opposition to sub- merge its substantive differences for the sake of the common goal of defeating Pinochet. The success of this strategy, moreover, opened the way to elections and gave the opposition sufficient bargaining power to negotiate a series of reforms to the 1980 Constitution, which while leaving the bulk of the latter's authoritarian features intact, provided the opposition greater room for political maneuver. At the same time, the continuing strength of the military regime and Pinochet's strong showing in the plebiscite maintained the urgency of preserving a united front and in fact enabled the opposition to perpetuate the plebiscite as the basis of political 10 Studies in Comparative International Development / Fall 1999 identification and struggle. The culmination of this process was Patricio Aylwin's victory in the 1989 presidential elections. But while successful, this strategy had other consequences that augured less well for democratization. By participating in the plebiscite and obtaining only limited constitutional reforms, the CPPD helped to consolidate the 1980 Constitu- tion and to restrict its own strategic options significantly. Moreover, despite its victory in the 1989 elections, it was unable to prevent the right from obtaining a majority in the Senate, a circumstance that was made possible by the regime's "binomial" electoral law and the existence of nine "designated" Senators. The CPPD's strategy also contributed to a demobilization and marginalization of popular sectors that had played a major role in opposing the military regime (most impor- tantly the labor movement), and thereby weakened the social base for more far- reaching change. And perhaps even more significantly, by being forced to act in accordance with the regime's transition procedures and timetable, the opposition was unable to prevent the regime from carrying out a second phase of structural transformations, the most dramatic of which were the phenomenal growth of ex- ports, a second wave of privatizations, the tremendous expansion of the privatized social security system as a source of investment capital, the emergence of a busi- ness community more structurally powerful and dynamic than ever before and firmly committed to the regime's economic model, and the greatly expanded pres- ence of transnational capital within the domestic economy. These structural changes, combined with a series of laws designed to further institutionalize the economic model, in turn made the transition a rather smooth and stable affair. In other words, by the end of the 1980s, the structural constraints had become sufficiently strong that it was possible for the military regime to loosen certain institutional con- straints and to tolerate the opposition's victories in the plebiscite and the 1989 elections. This changing set of institutional and structural constraints thus exposed a ma- jor flaw in the opposition's strategy. The implicit premise of that strategy was that it was necessary to give priority to the task of increasing the opposition's politico- institutional space before pushing for changes of a more substantive, socio-eco- nomic character at a later stage of political struggle. But the elimination of politico-institutional constraints was sufficiently gradual and limited that it was more than offset by the emergence of new structural constraints, so that by the time of the CPPD's victory in the 1989 elections, both its capacity and its inclina- tion to alter the regime's socio-economic model had been significantly dimin- ished. In fact, the CPPD's very preferences and objectives had undergone a significant change, as it began to look increasingly favorably on the regime's eco- nomic model and the dynamic potential of Chilean business. The importance of the latter to sustained economic growth also led the CPPD to moderate its pro- grammatic objectives considerably so as to overcome business' deep-seated dis- trust of the center-left and thereby avoid a destabilizing fall in investment. 17 The CPPD's positive assessment of the economic model contrasted with its critical attitude toward the profound social inequalities that had worsened over the course of the 1980s. It therefore called for increased wages and major reforms of the regime's repressive labor code. But this laid the basis for a potentially serious contradiction deriving from the central role that the flexible and extensive use of Barrett 11 cheap labor played in the regime's accumulation strategy and business' determined opposition to strengthening the rights and organizational power of labor. The CPPD's endorsement of the economic model also contrasted with its determination to elimi- nate the constraints built into the politico-institutional order bequeathed by the military regime. But here too, it faced a potentially serious contradiction, given the latter's importance to preserving the socio-economic model. Finding a formula for containing the tension between accumulation and the pressures for redistribution and inclusion thus emerged as the principal challenge facing the CPPD. However, as the sections that follow will show, the structural and institutional constraints that restricted the CPPD's maneuverability during the 1980s, in some respects grew stronger during the 1990s. And just as had occurred during the previous de- cade, as a result of those constraints, the CPPD's very preferences and objectives continued to undergo a process of moderation. The result was the consolidation of a neo-liberal elite pact, which rather than reconciling accumulation and inclusion/ distribution, has privileged the former over the latter.

IlL Development Strategy Without a doubt, the most consensual element of Chile's new compromise, and that to which the other elements have to a large degree been subordinated, is in the area of development strategy. In a sharp departure from the more interventionist development strategy advocated by the center-left throughout most of the 1980s, upon coming to power the CPPD gave highest priority to the maintenance of mac- roeconomic stability (and in particular the control of inflation), which was consid- ered critical to gaining the confidence of business and to creating a climate conducive to increased investment.t8 In fact, under the CPPD, Chile distinguished itself from the rest of Latin America by demonstrating a greater capacity to reconcile the competing objectives of low inflation, a stable real exchange rate, and sustained economic growth. This was in large part the result of the set of heterodox policies it deployed in regulating Chile's exchange and capital markets: a crawling peg exchange rate policy accompanied by occasional reevaluations and sterilized in- tervention; and controls on the entry of short-term capital. I9 The CPPD govern- ments also demonstrated greater fiscal responsibility than other transition governments in Latin America. Indeed, the CPPD was determined to avoid the experience of Chile's neighbors, where policies of a more populist character un- leashed inflationary pressures that subsequently undermined economic growth.

With respect to trade policy, the most important non-traditional export promotion policies initiated during the latter half of the 1980s went unaltered. 2~ In fact, only two major policy changes were introduced after 1990: the reduction in the uniform tariff level from 15 percent to 11 percent; and the negotiation of a series of free trade agreements. Finally, in the area of financial policy, the CPPD governments placed controls on short-term capital inflows, but left the military regime's liberal regulations governing FDI unaltered, while enacting other policies designed to create greater investment opportunities both domestically and internationally (most importantly, in the area of pension funds). The economic performance during 1990--1996 was perhaps the most impres- sive of any seven year period in modern Chilean history (see Table 1). GDP grew 12 Studies in Comparative International Development / Fall 1999 by an annual rate of 6.8 percent, inflation averaged 12.6 percent (falling to 6.6 percent in 1996), unemployment averaged 5.6 percent, the public sector registered an average surplus of 1.7 percent, and the rates of savings and fixed investment reached historic levels (averaging 26.8 percent and 25.2 percent, respectively).

Exports also continued to expand at a fast annual pace, nearly doubling in value between 1990 and 1995. Nonetheless, it is dangerous to extrapolate from this im- pressive performance, not so much because of the brief period it represents, but more importantly because of the underlying characteristics of the accumulation model. Consider the structure of production, and in particular the share of manu- facturing in GDP. The latter has declined steadily during the 1990s, falling from the already low level of 18.1 percent in 1989 to 16.2 percent in 1996, its lowest level since 1946. A somewhat similar pattern is evident in the composition of em- ployment, with industry's share falling from 16.8 percent in 1990 to 16.0 percent in 1997 (Central Bank 1998). Clearly, with an annual growth rate of 5.2 percent during 1990-1996, industry has hardly stagnated; but it is also clear that it is not the driving force of the economy. The character of Chile's accumulation model is further reflected in the compo- sition of its exports. While some observers have claimed that Chile entered the so- called "second export phase" during the 1990s (Dfaz 1996), Central Bank data indicate that between 1989 and 1997, the percentage of natural resource-intensive exports fell only slightly, from 92.1 percent to 87.2 percent. 2~ Using a different classification scheme, Ffrench-Davis and S~ez (1996) show that while manufac- tured exports grew from 5.4 percent in 1990 to 9.8 percent in 1993, only 0.8 per- cent were new industries with high technological content (up from 0.6 percent in 1990). Moreover, the component consisting of primary exports (i.e., unelaborated agricultural, forestry, and mining products) also increased from 27.8 percent to 31.8 percent. Meanwhile, semi-elaborated exports (e.g., refined copper, agroindustrial products, cellulose and paper, fishmeal), though falling from 65.4 percent to 56.5 percent, remained the largest component. Although these data ex- tend only through 1993, those provided by the Central Bank suggest that if any- thing, the component consisting of manufactured products is likely to have diminished after that date. 22 Thus, the vast majority of Chile's exports continue to be concentrated in low value-added natural resource-intensive products, a pattern which contrasts sharply with the composition of trade worldwide and among East Asian countries in par- ticular. Moreover, despite its considerable capacity in the area of macroeconomic policy-making, the CPPD governments were unable to prevent a 23.8 percent ap- preciation of the exchange rate between 1990 and 1996, a mild version of "Dutch disease" which poses an important obstacle to exports that are not reliant upon comparative advantages in natural resources. Furthermore, the growth in manu- factured exports has largely been concentrated in Latin America. 23 This is un- doubtedly the result of the economic recovery and greater exchange rate appreciation experienced by those countries, particularly Argentina and Brazil, which have ac- counted for roughly half of Chile's exports to the region. And although Latin America's share of Chilean exports grew rapidly from 12.5 percent in 1990 to 21 percent in 1994, it has declined since then. Asia's share, meanwhile, has grown steadily from 26.2 percent in 1990 to 34 percent in 1997 (Central Bank 1998). Its Barrett 13 4 o~ Jamr o r r :r O0 O0 ~ O0 0 o~ 0 0 r r tar% o ~D ML~ t"q~ x_/ ~ U ~ .~ ~ ~ o~ 14 Studies in Comparative International Development / Fall 1999 share of manufactured exports, however, declined from 6.2 percent in 1990 to 3.1 percent in 1993 (Meller and S~iez 1995). Thus, the composition of Chile's export markets, while more diversified than in the past, nonetheless continues to pose obstacles to industrial exports and to leave the economy vulnerable to external shocks. 24 The foregoing would seem to point to the need for an industrial policy strategy aimed at accelerating the move to a more advanced stage of export-led growth, as was in fact originally proposed in the CPPD's 1989 program (CPPD 1989:15). As it is, much of the success that Chile has enjoyed to date is the result of substantial state intervention, not only the exchange rate policies and special incentives for non-traditional exports implemented during the military regime 25 and the con- trols on short-term capital inflows instituted under the CPPD, but also the struc- tural reforms and sectoral promotion policies in agriculture and mining undertaken prior to 1973. Accelerating the move to a more advanced stage of export-led growth would therefore involve increasing the state's capacity to channel savings and investment selectively into higher value-added products that are less intensive in natural resources. Throughout the 1990s, however, the CPPD has maintained a cautious, hands off approach to fostering the economy's productive transformation. A clear illustration of this cautious approach was the government's program of support for small and medium-sized firms. According to Oscar Mufioz (1996), the old industrial policies based on sectoral priorities and selective state intervention do not fit into the new policy framework. The Aylwin administration therefore converted CORFO, the traditional industrial policy institution, into what it called a "third floor institution." This involved the allocation of subsidies "through the market and, in particular, through the commercial banks, subsidizing only the cost of ac- cess to financing when the latter poses entry barriers to small and medium-sized firms" (Mufioz 1996, 29-30). The government soon discovered, however, that the credit program was ineffective. Consequently, in mid- 1991, it launched a new pro- gram designed to foster associative networks of smaller firms, whose objective would be to improve the latter's access to new technologies, financing, training, marketing, etc. But while apparently somewhat more successful, the program has involved only a tiny minority of Chile's small and medium-sized firms and reflects the same reluctance to give the state a more active role in the economy's produc- tive transformation, z6 Another indication of the CPPD's limited capacity, or willingness, to influence the allocation of investment is the pattern of foreign investment during the 1990s.

As noted earlier, the CPPD introduced controls on the entry of short-term capital.

This policy has helped to generate a larger proportion of FDI inflows than the rest of Latin America, which would appear to offer greater promise for the country's productive development than a heavy reliance on short-term capital, as evidenced by the Mexican foreign exchange crisis of December 1994. At the same time, however, reliance on regulating short-term capital alone is of limited usefulness.

Unlike South Korea and Taiwan, which until recently carefully channeled FDI into selected industries and technological cooperation relationships with domestic firms, Chile has exercised little control over the direction of FDI. 27 It is therefore not surprising that 42.9 percent of FDI via Decree Law 600 during 1990-1997 has Barrett 15 been concentrated in mining and 28.4 percent in services (primarily banking, in- surance, securities, pension funds, and leasing). Only 14.2 percent, meanwhile, has been in industry, which in fact represents a significant decline from the 22.4 percent registered under the military regime (Central Bank 1997). Finally, the CPPD has made no effort to strengthen the state's institutional ca- pacity. The most powerful state institutions are the Ministry of Finance and the Central Bank, whose institutional bias favor a conservative approach to macroeco- nomic policy. By contrast, the Economy Ministry and CORFO, the traditional in- dustrial policy agencies, have been greatly weakened by the military regime. In fact, as we saw earlier, CORFO's institutional mission was reduced even further by the Aylwin administration. Furthermore, during 1995-1996, CORFO's payroll was cut by 30 percent and in 1997, both its ministerial status and its role as the holding company for state enterprises came to an end. 28 Moreover, although the CPPD had called in its 1989 program for the creation of a Ministry of Industry to replace the Economy Ministry as part of a proposed industrial policy strategy (CPPD 1989,15), this objective was never realized. The state's power is also restricted by the constitutional requirement that selective measures and state involvement in production gain the approval of Congress, where at least in the Senate, the rightist opposition has enjoyed a majority. In addition, both the Aylwin and Frei adminis- trations have denied important policy-making positions to those who are critical of the prevailing economic model, particularly the left wing of the Socialist Party.

Hence, even if the proponents of greater state intervention had a clear idea of the sort of intervention to engage in, they have lacked the institutional and political means to carry it out effectively. In sum, the macroeconomic performance of the Chilean economy under the CPPD has been nothing short of impressive. To a large degree, that performance has been the result of a combination of heterodox state policies (i.e., controls on short-term capital inflows, a highly interventionist exchange rate policy, and se- lective incentives for non-traditional exports) and favorable circumstances (e.g., the rapid growth of the pension funds, the recovery of neighboring countries' econo- mies, and an abundance of natural resources and unskilled labor). A close exami- nation, however, reveals that this accumulation model contains important limitations. This is clearly indicated by the low and declining share of industry in overall production, the continued heavy reliance on natural resource-intensive ex- ports, the sectoral allocation of foreign investment, the composition of Chile's export markets, and the declining profitability of the pension funds. 29 Moreover, the growth in Chile's labor force is rapidly decelerating and there is a growing scarcity of skilled labor. 3~ Finally, the high rates of growth in recent years have come at the price of severe environmental degradation, a problem that the CPPD has been reluctant to address for fear of alienating the business community and slowing the process of accumulation? l All of this suggests that without a more ambitious industrial policy strategy in which the state assumes a more active role in steering investment, and therefore a greater capacity to discipline capital, the current dynamism of Chile's accumulation model may prove unsustainable. 32 In- deed, what Chile may experience in the not too distant future is an economic slow- down reminiscent of the exhaustion of the initial, "easy" phase of ISI in the late 1940s and early 1950s. 16 Studies in Comparative International Development / Fall 1999 IV. Labor and Social Policy The second critical element of the CPPD's program, labor and social policy, was very much shaped by the priority given to development strategy. The CPPD's primary objective was to find a way of reconciling subordinate class demands for greater distributive equity with the maintenance of the accumulation model inher- ited from the military regime, an objective which was expressed in the slogan "Growth with Equity." However, as noted in section II, such an objective contained a potentially serious contradiction, given the functional importance of the military regime's labor and social policies to its accumulation model and business' strong opposition to strengthening the fights, organizational power, and income share of labor. In its 1989 program, the CPPD proposed a series of "profound" changes in the labor code aimed at restoring the "fundamental rights of workers" and creating equality in labor-capital relations (1989, 25-30). Soon after its victory in the De- cember 1989 elections, however, the Aylwin government began to view the mili- tary regime's Labor Plan more positively and even found that it contained many "modern" elements. 33 It insisted that its goal was to reconcile worker protection with labor market flexibility, 34 but while it attempted to stake out a middle posi- tion, in practice, it gave priority to the latter. Indeed, it argued incessantly that any reduction in flexibility would threaten the competitiveness of Chile's export economy. It also argued that changes in the labor code were not an effective means to strengthening the labor movement. If the latter sought to improve its bargaining position vis-h-vis business, it would have to achieve it by increasing its power as a social force rather than by relying on the state. 35 Moreover, the set of legislative proposals it presented to the Congress were a considerably watered down version of the CPPD program. For many within the labor movement and the business com- munity alike, it was also significant that the government introduced the first three of the four reform projects in the Senate, where it was in the minority. This effec- tively limited the range of debate and prevented the more open conflict that would have resulted had they been introduced in the Chamber of Deputies, where the CPPD enjoyed a majority. 36 The resulting reforms were a far cry from both the CPPD's own program and the aspirations of organized labor. Indeed, the overall thrust of the reforms was to preserve the fundamental features of the Labor Plan, introducing largely cosmetic changes that gave it the appearance of greater legitimacy. 37 Nonetheless, the gov- ernment hailed the new labor code as the first promulgated under a democratic regime in Chilean history. It also pointed to improvements in the material condi- tions of workers, the growth of unionization, and the absence of labor conflict as proof that its policies had succeeded in reconciling growth, stability, and equity.

Upon closer examination, however, the experience of labor during this period does not warrant such a positive assessment. Beginning with unemployment, it should be stressed that Chile's low unem- ployment rate (averaging 5.6 percent during 1990-1995) continues to mask the low quality and precarious character of employment experienced by the vast ma- jority of Chilean workers, a trend which, in fact, has grown during the 1990s. ~8 Moreover, while the 3.2 percent annual growth in real wages and 5.6 percent growth Barrett 17 in minimum wages during 1990-1995 signaled a major improvement over 1983- 1989, the real wage level attained in 1995 was only 9.3 percent greater than it had been a quarter century earlier and the minimum wage level remained 11.2 percent below that attained in 1981 (PET 1996). Without a doubt, the CPPD's most signifi- cant accomplishment has been the reduction in poverty from 38.6 percent in 1990 to 23.2 percent in 1996. But the rate of reduction has slowed considerably, and a large number of those who have left poverty (21A million or 18% of the population in 1994) remain precariously close to it. More importantly perhaps, the distribu- tion of income has worsened slightly, with 56.7 percent of national income going to the top 20 percent and only 4.1 percent going to the bottom 20 percent, a ratio of 13.8/1 (compared to 56.9 percent, 4.4 percent, and 12.9ll, respectively, in 1990) (Hardy 1997). In fact, Chile ranked as the sixth most unequal in a World Bank survey of sixty-four less developed countries (1997a), while its Gini Coefficient during the early 1990s (0.5469) far surpassed the average for Latin America and the Caribbean (0.4931), the most inequitable region in the world (World Bank 1997b). The Aylwin administration also argued that it had fostered a growth in unioniza- tion and peaceful labor-capital relations. In fact, the rate of unionization increased from 11.5 percent in 1989 to 15.4 percent in 1991, while strikes involved only 0.6 percent of the working population during 1990-1995. Despite the increase in union- ization through 1991, however, it declined in the years that followed, falling to 12.7 percent in 1995 and registering a total growth of only 10.4 percent during the entire period (and starting from a very low level). Particularly striking is the de- cline in the absolute number of union members after 1992, which fell by 86,000, or 11.9 percent, between 1993 and 1995. Moreover, when taking into consider- ation only enterprise unions (still the only ones capable of bargaining collectively), the rate of unionization for 1995 falls to 8.3 percent, which in relation to 1989 represents an increase of only 5.1 percent (and starting from an even lower level). 39 Meanwhile, the average size of unions fell from 71.3 workers in 1989 to 50 in 1995, a 29.9 percent decline. Finally, the number of strikes, striking workers, and days lost during 1990-1995 increased by 256 percent, 261 percent, and 258 per- cent, respectively, over 1983-1989. This apparently alarming growth in strike ac- tivity should not be regarded as significant, given the small percentage of the workforce involved and the short duration of strikes (an average of 12.8 days). 4~ But neither should the much more modest growth in unionization. Indeed, rather than evidence of peaceful capital-labor relations, the low level of strike activity can more accurately be interpreted as evidence of the fundamental power imbal- ance between capital and labor. Government actions in the area of social policy provide an equally clear illus- tration of the limited priority given by the CPPD to distributive equity. Indeed, the most salient feature of social policy under the CPPD is its basic continuity with the policy orientation of the military regime, the main thrust of which was to reduce the state's role in the provision of social services, transferring it as much as pos- sible to the private sector. Thus, with respect to social spending, the CPPD main- tained the military regime's emphasis on targeting social spending toward the poorest social groups, combining it with more universal programs, particularly in education and health care? ! It also raised the level of social spending by 7 percent annually, or from 58.7 percent of total government spending during 1987-1989 to 18 Studies in Comparative International Development / Fall 1999 62.6 percent during 1990-1995 (Ruiz-Tagle 1996, 29), the bulk of which was fi- nanced by the 1990 tax reform. It bears noting, however, that in 1993, the poorest 20 percent of the population received only 18.5 percent of social expenditure, while the richest 20 percent received 26.6 percent. If pension contributions, which con- stituted over 40 percent of social spending, are excluded, the share of the poorest quintile would increase to 28.3 percent and that of the upper quintile would de- cline to 12.7 percent; but the redistributive effect would still be quite small (Sc"tt 1995). 42 An important component of the increased revenues generated by the tax reform, moreover, came from an increase in the Value Added Tax (VAT) from 16 percent to 18 percent, a regressive form of taxation which in recent years accounts for roughly 50 percent of total tax revenue. It is this tax, in fact, that the CPPD has been most determined to maintain. 43 Furthermore, the problems in health and edu- cation remain severe, especially in the former, where inequalities are great. 44 Fi- nally, the CPPD abandoned its earlier calls for reforms of the military regime's privatized social security system designed to make it more "solidaristic" and in- crease worker participation in the administration of the pension funds. 45 Instead, it focused its efforts on loosening the restrictions on fund investments as part of the capital market reforms passed in 1993. 46 But many of the same trends that were a source of concern during the 1980s (with respect to coverage, administrative costs, and corporate control) continued, and even worsened, during the 1990s. 47 And although the system continued to generate significant savings during the first half of the 1990s, in recent years the profitability of the funds has fallen dramatically. While business was very pleased with the CPPD's labor and social policies, 48 the labor movement was left profoundly disillusioned. 49 Indeed, the Unitary Workers Central (CUT), Chile's principal labor central, strongly denounced the government's failure to fulfill its program and the "insensitivity" of the economic team, and made a series of threats directed at both the government and business. None of the threats were ever carried out, however, in large part because of the CUT's organi- zational weakness and its fear of undermining the still fragile process of transition.

But this only served to deepen the internal divisions that had plagued the CUT throughout the 1980s, and rather than seeing its organizational and mobilizational capacity increase, the absence of tangible victories made the CUT appear weak and insignificant. 5~ The sense of disillusionment only deepened under the Frei administration. For while the CUT had been extremely disappointed by the Aylwin administration's policies, it had at least enjoyed strong personal ties with some of its principal policy makers. The same could not be said of the Frei administration, which was perceived as cold, distant, and even more importantly, strongly pro- business. 51 The CUT's disillusionment was reinforced by the government's failure to offer a clear response to the set of labor reforms it had proposed soon after the new administration was inaugurated. As a result, the CUT quickly distanced itself from the government and pursued a more aggressive, mobilizational strategy. 52 The government gave in to the pressure in January 1995, when it submitted a new package of labor reforms to the Congress23 The CUT reacted favorably to the reforms and reestablished relations, but their rejection by the right and business, and the government's less than energetic efforts to see them passed, led the CUT to resume its confrontational approach. 54 Furthermore, the rising tensions within the labor movement failed to abate, as evidenced by the declining support for the PDC Barrett 19 and a surge in support for the Communists in a series of federation elections. 55 The latter's resurgence only served to worsen relations between CPPD trade unionists, on the one hand, and their parties and the government, on the other. It also helped to set the stage for a dramatic CUT election in April 1996, in which the CUT's Socialist vice president brokered a deal with the Communists, thus marking the collapse of the CPPD alliance within the labor movement/6 In sum, the foregoing provides strong evidence that the CPPD's stated goal of reconciling "growth with equity" can hardly be considered a success; indeed, it is increasingly being labeled a failure (Fazio 1997; Hardy 1997; Lavandero 1996).

Among the factors explaining this outcome are the precarious structure of employ- ment, the extreme concentration of asset ownership, and the limited redistributive effect of the CPPD's tax and social policies. An equally important factor, however, has been organized labor's weak bargaining position vis-~t-vis capital. Throughout this period, the CPPD governments have argued that the CUT's trouble has been its obsession with legislation that would afford it greater protection from the state, rather than focusing on the task of strengthening itself as a social force capable of bargaining with capital on an even footing. But while by its own admission, the CUT could have done more to build its organizational capacity, the overwhelming effect of the labor legislation enacted during these years was to create legal ob- stacles to strengthening the labor movement and putting it on an equal footing with business. Moreover, more than the labor movement being obsessed with its protection, the government has been obsessed with maintaining labor market flex- ibility and the confidence of business, the economic consequences of which have not been questioned. Most importantly, as argued in section I, by enabling busi- ness to place almost the entire burden of adjustment on labor, a flexible labor market can actually impede innovation. An equally, if not more justifiable objec- tive, therefore, would be to impose greater flexibility (or disciplipe) on capital by protecting labor. Hence, the "stability" in labor-capital relations witnessed during this period has not been the product of a national "consensus," but rather the in- ability of a weak and marginalized labor movement to prevent an accommodation between the government, business, and the right. The growing turmoil in the labor movement suggests, however, that this stability may not endure.

V. State Decision-Making The third and final critical element of the CPPD's program concerned its pro- posals for politico-institutional reform. The principal target of those proposals was the 1980 Constitution and its supporting laws, which were no less central to the military regime's transformative project than its social and economic "accomplish- ments." Indeed, they were designed specifically to prevent the latter's unmaking, as well as to block the type of politicizatioo .nat had undermined the previous civilian regime. More specifically, the Consti,ution established nearly total presi- dential domination over the Congress, while at the same time countering the president's powers by expanding the prerogatives and autonomy of several state agencies (most importantly, the Constitutional Tribunal, the Central Bank, the Comptroller General, the National Security Council, and the Armed Forces). The Constitution also sought to institutionalize the military regime's economic model 20 Studies in Comparative International Development / Fall 1999 by elevating its basic principles to constitutional rank. And it sought to prevent the politicization that had undermined the pre-1973 political system by imposing se- vere restrictions on the scope of popular representation (most notably, by limiting the powers of Congress, creating the autonomous state agencies mentioned above, requiring that a third of the Senate be non-elected and instituting a so-called "bi- nomial" electoral system). In short, the politico-institutional structure embodied in the 1980 Constitution was designed to limit both the scope and the accessibility of state decision-making, thereby preserving a neo-liberal socio-economic order. 57 As noted in section II, in 1989 the CPPD succeeded in negotiating a series of modest constitutional reforms) 8 No sooner had the reforms been approved, how- ever, than the CPPD incorporated those that it failed to achieve as key features of its government program (CPPD 1989, 3). Indeed, it was in this area that the CPPD advanced perhaps its clearest agenda of change. But this was also the area in which it saw its objectives most consistently frustrated. The only significant advances achieved during this entire period, in fact, were accords over the holding of mu- nicipal elections (the first since 1971) and the shortening of the presidential term from eight to six years. In all other respects, the CPPD confronted the permanent veto of the rightist majority in the Senate (see Table 2), which was itself a product of the military regime's institutional design (i.e., the designated senators and the binomial electoral system). At the same time, the CPPD's actions in this area provide further evidence of the evolving character of its preferences, objectives, and internal relations of power.

This was already evident, in fact, during the negotiation of the 1989 reforms. At the time of the Constitution's promulgation, the opposition strongly condemned the manner in which it institutionalized the military regime's economic model, arguing that the economic norms established in a constitution should be suffi- ciently broad and flexible to make possible the application of diverse economic schemes, including a mixed economy and democratic socialism. 59 By 1989, how- ever, this emphasis on the Constitution's link to the military regime's economic model had disappeared. The one exception was the CPPD's opposition to the new Central Bank law. But even here, it dropped its earlier criticism of the Bank's institutional autonomy in exchange for altering the composition of its board of directors. On this basis, it easily reached an accord with the military regime in August 1989. The CPPD also came to look more favorably on other aspects of the politico- institutional order inherited from the military regime. With respect to the electoral law, for example, the eagerness for reform among government officials was not always consistent with the government's public pronouncements. 6~ Indeed, the electoral system was most beneficial to the largest parties (especially the PDC; see Table 2), as well as the strongest candidates within each party. 6~ It also had the effect of fostering the emergence of two large electoral blocs--thus reinforcing the division between "authoritarians" and "democrats" generated by the 1988 plebi- scite-and it helped to keep the govemment coalition together. 62 Moreover, while important elements of the CPPD remained critical of the excessively presidentialist character of the 1980 Constitution, others, particularly those who occupied the Executive branch, came to view it much more positively. 63 In fact, the key minis- try in both CPPD administrations has been the Secretary General of the Presi- Barrett 21 I TM I L ! 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Z 0 b 0 E c~ 22 Studies in Comparative International Development / Fall 1999 dency, a creation of the military regime which the Aylwin administration elevated to ministerial rank. 64 It is also the case that the institutional constraints built into the Constitution have enabled the CPPD to make policy in a technocratic, anti- populist fashion. Indeed, according to one Finance Ministry official, the insulation and autonomy afforded to policy-makers by the current institutional environment is a major reason why "the period of conflictual politics, inefficient policymaking, and economic stagnation, which lasted for more than half a century, is finally coming to an end" (Velasco 1994, 411).

65 Finally, the fact that Constitutional reforms had little chance for approval al- lowed the CPPD to reap some important political dividends. Most importantly, their rejection enabled the CPPD to portray itself as the force for democratization and the right as its obstacle, thereby maintaining the political cleavage between "democrats" and "authoritarians" established in the plebiscite and strengthening its hold on power. In fact, during the Aylwin administration, the reform proposals were introduced into Congress with full knowledge that they would be rejected. 66 This tactic had a significant effect on the right, particularly the moderate wing of the largest opposition party, National Renovation (RN), whose entire political strat- egy turned on shedding the authoritarian legacy of the military regime in order to put an end to the political division created by the plebiscite. Indeed, the issue nearly caused RN to splinter in April 1996, as seven of its senators voted against a constitutional reform package brokered by party president, Andrfs Allamand, and the Frei administration. 67 Thus, the CPPD's enthusiasm for politico-institutional reforms tended to wane over time, as some powerful elements of the coalition began to see certain advan- tages in the institutional order bequeathed by the military regime. But this evolu- tion in the CPPD's position was not without negative consequences. First, it was cause for serious division within the coalition. This was most true during the Frei administration, which at the outset, placed little importance on politico-institu- tional reforms. Indeed, in a reversal of the strategy adopted by the CPPD in the late 1980s of seeking to expand its political space in order to realize greater socio- economic change, the Frei administration spoke of a separation between its socio- economic and politico-institutional goals. Emphasis was to be placed on the former, while the latter was to be postponed until the end of Frei's term, at which point, apparently, they would be introduced largely for their electoral effects. This strat- egy triggered a major controversy and only intense pressure from within the coali- tion (particularly, the Socialists) forced the Frei administration to put the reforms back on the agenda. Even then, however, many perceived that the government did so only to get the issue out of the way, so as to concentrate on its socio-economic agenda. 68 Second, the institutional restrictions built into the Constitution not only severely limit the democratic character of the state, but also its repertoire of strategic op- tions. As we saw in section III, the state does enjoy a degree of technocratic capac- ity in the area of macroeconomic policy. Moreover, the state's institutional features (e.g., the autonomy of the Central Bank, the Executive's control over the budget, and the constitutional restrictions on state intervention) have enabled it to resist the sort of rent-seeking that contributed to macroeconomic instability in the de- cades preceding military rule. However, not only is the state's maneuverability in Barrett 2 3 this area limited by the heightened international mobility of capital, 69 but domes- tically this is an essentially negative form of autonomy. In other words, the state can preserve its autonomy only by preserving its neutrality, for it is in no position to make the sort of selective interventions characteristic of East Asian industrial policy, without quickly succumbing to rent-seeking pressures. Most importantly, it lacks the means to discipline private capital and steer investment into productive activities, a defining feature of the East Asian model at the height of its success. 7~ Business, not surprisingly, has been strongly opposed to further Constitutional reforms, seeing in them a serious threat to Chile's new socio-economic order, vl A growing imbalance has thus resulted, as the state's institutional capacity has not kept pace with either the growing power of capital or the demands of Chile's ma- turing export-oriented economy. 72 Finally, the state's capacity to make policy in a coherent, technocratic fashion has in significant measure been made possible by the nature of the government's relationship to the CPPD. This was best illustrated by the Aylwin administration, whose policy-making effectiveness was greatly enhanced by the autonomy granted to it by the CPPD. Because of their concern for ensuring the stability of the Aylwin administration, which they regarded as one of transition, the CPPD parties feared that a more active role on their part might generate some of the instability that plagued governments in the decade preceding military rule. Moreover, Aylwin pro- ceeded to designate a cabinet, which while dominated by Christian Democrats, was composed of a group of moderate figures who had played key roles in the CPPD's formation and whose ties to each other and loyalty to his administration rivaled those to their respective parties. These characteristics, in fact, earned them the nickname Partido Transversal. v3 The Frei administration's relationship to the CPPD parties, by contrast, has been very different. Not only have those parties been determined to play a more active role (now that the transition is no longer perceived to be in jeopardy), but Frei, who himself was largely politically inactive during the 1980s, was not able to draw on a group like the Partido Transversal.

Thus, after first putting together a cabinet composed of high-ranking party officials, he resorted to relying on a group of close personal friends. The result was a deterioration in the government's relation- ship with the CPPD and a great deal less policy coherence than that exhibited by the Aylwin administration. 74 Moreover, there has been a growing competition both among and within the parties of the coalition. What is striking about that competi- tion, however, is the degree to which it has focused on the distribution of political power, much more than substantive policy differences. 75 Furthermore, the CPPD has paid a price for this growing preoccupation with power. This was evident in the string of Communist victories in student and union federation elections during the mid-1990s. Even more alarming was the outcome of the 1997 Congressional elec- tions (see Table 2); while the CPPD lost only one Senate seat and maintained its share of seats in the Chamber of Deputies, it saw its total votes fall by over 1 million and its share of the vote fall to 50 percent. But more alarming still was the number of voters who turned in blank or defaced ballots (over 1.23 million or nearly 1 out of 5) and the similar number of young people who did not register to vote. Thus, while the CPPD remained the country's most important political group- ing, there are growing signs that it is losing its popular support. 24 Studies in Comparative International Development / Fall 1999 In sum, the decision-making apparatus inherited from the military regime has contributed to stability during the 1990s by limiting state action to a narrow range of strategic options and restricting popular representation. In this respect, it re- sembles the structure of state decision-making that prevailed during the 1930s and 1940s, the heyday of Chile's first compromise. However, if Chile's experience from 1952 to 1973 is any guide, that same institutional structure may subsequently become a major source of instability if the state is unable to respond to changing economic conditions by carrying out timely changes in the country's development strategy, if it is subjected to rising pressure for expanded popular participation, or if the governing coalition suffers a breakdown. 76 VI. Conclusion The singularity of the Chilean experience has long been the fact that while it has undergone processes that have occurred elsewhere in Latin America, it took those processes further, such that their contradictions and consequences stood out in greater relief. This was true of its first socio-political compromise during the 1930s and 1940s, the instability and institutional collapse that was its legacy from the early 1950s to the early 1970s, and the process of authoritarian transformation following 1973. So too with Chile's new socio-political compromise; indeed, Chile is today widely regarded as the most promising of Latin America's new democra- cies. But as this article has demonstrated, it is also a great exemplar of how democ- racy can be severely hampered by institutional and structural constraints: among the former, an institutional apparatus that limits state action to a narrow range of strategic options, impedes popular access to state decision-making, and restricts the bargaining power of labor; and among the latter, an accumulation model that relies on the country's comparative advantages in natural resources and the flex- ible use of cheap labor, an extreme concentration of wealth and income, and a powerful domestic business class with strong links to international capital and determined to resist all but the most modest changes in the socio-economic status quo.

In short, Chile's new compromise can be characterized as a neo-liberal elite pact that has privileged accumulation over both inclusion and distribution. This outcome is no accident. Indeed, it has not departed significantly from the sort of post-military order envisioned by the authors of the military regime's trans- formative project. Moreover, the principal political opponents of military rule adopted a strategy that placed a high priority on stability and envisioned democra- tization as a gradual process, which has had the effect of privileging continuity over change. Thus, not unlike Chile's previous compromise, there are significant limitations built into its current one. Whether that compromise is capable of gener- ating the strategic capacity that would enable the state to adapt to changing cir- cumstances, and in a manner compatible with continued political stability and ongoing democratization, will depend on the nature of the relations between the party system, business, and the state. The key question is whether those relations are sufficiently resilient as to foster an evolving consensus capable of accommo- dating greater demands for social and political integration and changing patterns of state intervention, or, as in the case of Chile's previous compromise, are so narrow and contingent as to prevent such an evolving consensus. Barrett 2 5 With respect to political parties, the ability of the parties of the CPPD to forge a governing majority and implement a coherent policy program constitutes a sig- nificant historical accomplishment and distinguishes Chile from many other Latin American countries where weak and fragmented party systems have hampered the capacity of governments to resolve social and economic problems through demo- cratic means. The existence of a center-left coalition, itself a major historical ac- complishment, also places the Chilean government in a stronger negotiating position vis-t~-vis business and its party allies, thereby increasing the prospects for the so- cial and political integration of subordinate classes. At the same time, however, neither the integrity of the coalition, its ability to continue the current approach to policy-making, nor its capacity to bring about greater social and political integra- tion can be taken for granted. In fact, there are serious tensions within the coali- tion, as well as between it and the executive. The suppression of those tensions has largely been facilitated by the perpetuation of the political cleavage created by the 1988 plebiscite and the resulting lack of political alternatives outside of the CPPD and the principal parties of the right. However, as soon as Chilean politics is no longer defined in terms of a referendum on Pinochet and the military regime, the ability of the coalition to maintain unity and make policy in a non-populist, supra- party, and technocratic fashion will diminish. Indeed, such a process has clearly begun under the Frei administration, though the rising levels of disillusionment remain without a clear, organized expression. Furthermore, much of the consensus that exists within the governing coalition over development strategy is more the result of inertia than of a clearly defined strategic choice. This suggests that should structural conditions change and economic growth become increasingly difficult, the current consensus may not be maintained and, more significantly, the CPPD may well be ill prepared to chart a coherent alternative course. The CPPD demonstrates even greater short-comings with respect to the promo- tion of social and political integration. The current situation strongly resembles an elite pact, as there exist greater understanding and lines of communication be- tween the parties in power and big business than between those parties and their popular constituencies among subordinate classes. Indeed, not unlike the Popular Front fifty years ago, the government is engaged in an accommodation with forces not part of its electoral coalition, pursuing policies far more in line with the latter's interests and demands than with those of their own supporters. This is a potentially risky formula, as Chile's experience in the 1940s demonstrates, but it can be sus- tained as long as the economy continues to grow, labor remains weak, and subor- dinate class actors perceive there is little alternative to the coalition in power.

However, it bears repeating that once growth slows and/or the sense of limited alternatives fades, social conflicts are likely to intensify and the political pressure for meeting popular demands will likely increase, as the events of 1996-1997 would seem to indicate. This could lead to greater popular participation in state decision-making and the construction of a new consensus based on more equitably distributed sacrifices and benefits. Such a development, which approximates some- thing of a transition from an elite pact toward a democratic class compromise, would in turn depend upon stronger ties with better organized subordinate class actors, particularly the labor movement. It would also depend upon the ability to confront potential opposition from business and the right. To the degree that those 26 Studies in Comparative International Development / Fall 1999 conditions fail to obtain, however, Chile's multiparty system could resume some of the populist, polarizing, and immobilizing tendencies it exhibited in the past. Finally, Chilean business is far less defensive and enjoys a much more solid position within the political and economic order than at any time in the last sev- enty-five years. Moreover, as a result of this process, there exists a pragmatic ele- ment that has gained strength and has contributed to the forging of Chile's new socio-political compromise. This tendency may well continue, particularly if the sense of threat to capital diminishes even further. At the same time, how- ever, the state's inability to discipline capital and steer investment into activi- ties embodying higher levels of technological sophistication brings into question the long-term viability of the current accumulation model. Furthermore, one of the side effects of a more powerful business community is its greater de- termination to limit the participation of subordinate classes. Indeed, as was true during the 1932-1973 period, there are strong limits to the reformist inclinations of even the more pragmatic and conciliatory elements within Chile's economic elite. It is altogether possible that, despite recent developments among social move- ments and at the polls, the civilian regime in place today in Chile can become consolidated and remain stable. Indeed, Chile may live up to its promoters' claim of being a model of the new Latin American democracy. But if that is the case, it will be a highly restricted model, a neo-liberal elite pact characterized by a very limited scope of social and political integration and an inequitable distribution of income. If it is not, it is possible that the regime will be unable to provide the institutional mechanism for reconciling the tension between the imperative of sus- tained accumulation in today's international economy and the conflicts over inclu- sion and distribution that until now have largely been held in check.

Notes Research for this article was made possible by grants from the John D. and Catherine T.

MacArthur Foundation, the Fulbright Institute for International Education, and the Institute for the Study of World Politics. I would also like to thank Gretchen Bauer, Vivek Chibber, Ken Roberts, Gay Seidman, and especially Rachel Schurman for their comments on earlier ver- sions of this article. 1. For a full treatment of the emergence, crisis, and collapse of Chile's previous compromise and the process of authoritarian transformation that followed, see Barrett (1997), chapters Three through Six. 2. This section is a substantially shortened version of Barrett (1997), chapter Two.

3. The term "strategic capacity" is borrowed from Frederic Deyo who defines it as the "capacity to direct...resources on behalf of strategic development goals...and to generate flexible strat- egies that foster developmentally favorable linkages to the world economy" (1987, 238). 4. See, for example, Chang and Rowthorn (1995) and Putterman and Rueschemeyer (1992). See also the extensive literature on East Asian development, which neo-orthodox observers have erroneously attributed to a nearly exclusive reliance on market forces. A partial bibliography would include Amsden (1989); Chu (1995); Haggard (1990); Maclntyre (1994); and Wade (1990). 5. For discussions of the limits imposed on macroeconomic policy by the globalization of fi- nance, see Cerny (1993), Frieden (1991), Goodman and Pauly (1993), Stewart (1984), Underhill (1991), and Webb (1991). 6. See also Paul Doremus, et al., (1998) and Kozul-Wright and Rowthorn (1998). Barrett 2 7 7. For a somewhat similar argument, see Boix (1998).

8. Amsden (1992); Fajnzylber (1990); Fishlow (1990); Gereffi (1995); Hikkino and Amsden (1994); Pack (1992); Pack and Westphal (1986); Shapiro and Taylor (1990). 9. Clearly, the pursuit of an industrial policy strategy carries significant risks of its own; indeed, the landscape is littered with examples of failure, including Chile prior to military rule. None- theless, a close reading of the development literature and of history demonstrates that there are in fact very few successful cases of "catching up" among late developers, and that these have relied heavily on industrial and strategic trade policies. 10. For an elaboration of this argument, see Barrett 1999. See also Amsden (1989, 1992).

11. Indeed, as Chile's experience in the two decades preceding military rule demonstrates, state efforts to impose its objectives on a resistant capitalist class can prove truly disastrous. See Barrett (1997) and Barrett and Chibber (1998). 12. This is not to say that labor and social policies always succeed in reducing inequalities. To the contrary, they are as likely to preserve the structure of inequality, or create a new one, as they are to correct it (Esping-Andersen 1990). 13. The degree to which this is true will vary with the degree to which an economy depends on exports, but even in a heavily export-oriented economy, wages are not only a cost of produc- tion. As long as the domestic market is also growing, rising wages will also be a source of demand. 14. Pontusson (1991, 1992); Landesmann (1992); and Okimoto (1989).

15. A clear example of this is the growing trend toward independent Central Banks, which are more likely to pursue restrictive monetary policies than non-independent banks. 16. On the question of central bank independence, for example, in those countries where employ- ment and welfare goals have been most fully attained (Sweden, Norway, Austria), central banks have enjoyed little independence (Uusitalo 1984; Epstein and Schor 1990; Scharpf 1990; Landesmann and Vartiainen 1992). Similarly, in those countries where industrial policy has been most successfully implemented (e.g., Japan, South Korea, France), central banks have had little autonomy from executive authority. 17. For detailed discussions of the evolving strategic orientation of business and parties during this period, see Barrett (1998a and forthcoming). 18. The business community made it clear from the start that it would not tolerate an alteration of the economic model. For its part, the government sought to gain business' confidence by dem- onstrating that it had no intention of doing so. The government was also very careful in its choice of economic team and other key policy makers, selecting figures who were pro-market and/or were drawn from the business world. For the most part, moreover, business leaders had little difficulty gaining access to the economic team. For more on business' posture toward the CPPD and its policies during the 1990s, see Barrett (1998a). 19. For detailed discussions of Chile's macroeconomic policies, see Agosin (1995); Agosln and Ffrench-Davis (1996); Ffrench-Davis, et al., (1995); Aninat and Larrain (1996); Ffrench-Davis and Lab~ (1996); and Laban and Larrain (1993). 20. These included: (1) the elimination of stamp taxes on exports and of the value-added tax on investment for exports; (2) a refund (draw-back) of 10 percent on the net return of exports amounting to US$2.5 million or less, specifically designed for emerging non-traditional ex- ports; (3) expansion of the list of capital goods and intermediate inputs benefiting from re- duced import duties; and (4) subsidization of the forestry industry. 21. Natural resource-intensive exports include: mining; agriculture; forestry; fishing; food and beverages; wood and furniture; and paper, pulp, and paper derivatives. Chile's main non-natu- ral resource-intensive exports are categorized as: textiles; chemical and petroleum products; basic metallic products; metallic and electrical products; transport equipment; and other. 22. According to the Central Bank (1997), after peaking at 44.1 percent in 1993, industrial exports declined to 41.4 percent in 1997, while the component consisting of non-natural resource- intensive manufactures fell from 13.6 percent to 12.8 percent (during the same period, mining exports rose from 43 percent to 48.4 percent). This trend is corroborated by the Association of Manufactured Exports (ASEXMA), whose own data indicate that after peaking at 18.9 percent of total exports in 1993, manufactured exports have fallen since then: 1994 (17.3%); 1995 (15.4%); 1996 (17.8%); 1997 (15.2%). On the basis of this data, in fact, ASEXMA has re- 28 Studies in Comparative International Development / Fall 1999 jected the government's claim that Chile has entered the second export phase (see Qud Pasa, September 13, 1997, p. 60). 23. During 1990-1993, Latin America's share of Chile's manufactured exports grew from 36.8 percent to 53.8 percent (Meller and S~tez 1995). 24. The vulnerability of the Chilean economy can be seen in the effects of the East Asian crisis of 1997-1998, which has caused a significant fall in Chile's export revenues and prices and the value of its currency, as well as the growing balance of payments deficits. These problems have in turn forced the government to make budget cuts and to enact policies to defend the peso, including an end to capital controls. The Chilean economy is also likely to be adversely af- fected by the more recent Brazilian crisis. 25, According to Shez and Ffrench-Davis (1996), the great majority of Chile's manufactured ex- ports (70 percent in 1994) have benefited from special incentives. 26. For more on the government's program of support for small and medium-sized firms, see Rom~in and Rojas (1994). 27. For in-depth discussions of foreign investment in Chile, see Agosfn (1995); Agosfn and Ffrench- Davis (1996); Ffrench-Davis et al., (1995); Mayorga and Montt (1995); and OECD (1997). On East Asia, see Lall (1995). 28. Economist Intelligence Unit, Country Report: Chile, 4th quarter, 1996.

29. The annual rate of return registered in 1995-1996 (0.5%) represents the worst two year perfor- mance of the system since its inception in 1981. According to press reports, this poor perfor- mance continued during 1997-1998. 30. According to the World Bank (1995, 211), the average annual growth in Chile's labor force declined from 2.4 percent during 1970-1980 to 2.2 percent in 1980-1993 and is projected to fall to 1.4 percent during 1993-2000. 31. For treatments of the environmental consequences of Chile's economic model, see Claude (1997); Schurman (1996); and Quiroga and Van Hauwermeiren (1996). 32. For a similar conclusion, see Agacino (1996).

33. Author interview with Guillermo Campero, Labor Ministry adviser, Santiago, July 8, 1993.

34. Author interview with Joseph Ramos, economic consultant to Labor Ministry, Santiago, July 10, 1993. See also Joseph Ramos (1993) and Cort~zar (1993, 26-28). 35. Labor policy was therefore "based on the understanding that in both public and private compa- nies, labor relations should be defined by workers and management, autonomously of the state" (Cortfizar 1996, 120). 36. It also enabled the government to put the blame for the limited character of the reforms on the rightist opposition. This view was expressed in many interviews with labor and business leaders and labor lawyers. In fact, according to Alvaro Pizarro, the technical adviser on labor reforms of the leading opposition party, RN, the government worked very closely with RN in defining those limits and making certain that the opposition provided the government with the necessary counterbal- ance to demands for more far-reaching change (author interview, Santiago, May 5, 1993). 37. For a detailed discussion of the 1990-1993 labor reforms, see Barrett (1998b).

38. Diaz (1997, 172-175); Agacino (1995, 134-136); and M~rquez Belloni (1994, 132-143).

39. Moreover, fully 30 percent of the legally constituted unions in 1993 were in recess (up from 21.7 percent in 1991), which, if applied to 1995, would bring the rate of unionization for that year down to 8.9 percent for all unions and only 5.8 percent for enterprise unions. 40. The data in this paragraph are drawn from Fffas (1992, 1994, and 1996).

41. It also implemented new programs designed to help the poor to help themselves through group formation. The best example is the Social Investment and Solidarity Fund (FOSIS). For de- tailed discussions of CPPD social policies, see Scott (1995); Raczynski (1995); Vergara (1993 and 1994); and Rufz-Tagle (1996). 42. For more on the redistributive effect of social spending, see Qu~ Pasa, July 22, 1995.

43. On the CPPD's position toward the VAT, and its regressive consequences, see Qud Pasa, Au- gust 9, 1997. 44. The recent fall in export revenue and decline in the value of the peso resulting from the East Asian crisis have led the Frei administration to make budget cuts, especially in health. 45. The CPPD did not disagree that the old social security system was in crisis and in need of reform. In fact, reforming the system had been on the agenda of every government since the Barrett 29 early 1950s. The central feature of the social security reform of 1981 was the replacement of the old state-run, pay-as-you-go pension system with a private system of individual capitaliza- tion administered by private corporations, or AFPs. For detailed discussions of Chile's new social security system, see Arellano (1984); Barrientos (1993); Diamond and Valdrs-Prieto (1994); Gillion and Bonilla (1992); Marcel and Arenas (1992); and Mesa-Lago (1989). 46. According to Joaqufn Vial, the government also felt compelled to incorporate safeguards to ensure the transparency of the system because, given the system's lack of legitimacy, it would have been difficult to obtain political support for legislation that sought only to diversify the pension funds' investment portfolios (Vial 1996, 35). 47. For discussions of recent developments in the pension system, see Rufz-Tagle (1994 and 1997) and Albuquerque (1997). 48. Many candidly acknowledged privately that no real changes had been made in the labor code and that their flexibility vis-ti-vis labor had not been reduced (author interviews, October 1992- July 1993). This is not to say, however, that the labor reforms came without a major fight, particularly within the business community. For more on this, see Barrett (1998a and 1998b). 49. The evolution of labor's relations with the CPPD and business is examined in greater detail in Barrett (1998b). 50. Author interviews with labor leaders, October 1992-July 1993. For more on the level of disil- lusionment within the labor movement, see the results of a survey of 200 labor leaders in Sapag (1993). 51. Frei and several of his inner circle were closely tied to the business community (Barrett 1998a). The CUT reacted by denouncing the government for favoring business over labor (Hoy, Janu- ary 10-16, 1994 and December 12-18, 1994; APSI, July 11-24, 1994). 52. See Ercilla, July 15, 1994; and Hoy, December 12-18, 1994 and January 2-8, 1995.

53. For details, see QudPasa, January 7, 1995; Hoy, January 12-15, 1995; and Ercilla, January 13, 1995. 54. APSI, August 21-September 3, 1995.

55. The most dramatic example was the PC's victory in the Teachers Association, the largest of the CUT's federations and a traditional PDC stronghold. For details of the PC's resurgence, see Hoy, August 12-18, 1996. 56. The events leading up to the election were quite complicated. For details, see Qu~ Pasa, April 29, 1996; and Hoy, April 22-28 and April 29-May 5, 1996 57. The restrictions on state decision-making built into the Constitution reflected the neo-liberal conception of democracy of its principal author, Jaime Guzmfin. Guzm~in contended that the problems facing Chile were increasingly socio-economic in character, and that these required ever more technical and complex solutions that could only be realized by concentrating deci- sion-making power in the Executive and limiting the irresponsible tendencies of parliamentary assemblies. On the other hand, he argued that the scope of state decision-making also had to be restricted. Indeed, according to Guzmfin, a stable democracy is a system in which one's adver- saries can come to power, but are unable to pursue a course of action much different from that which one would pursue were one to come to power. Democratic stability, in other words, depends not so much on who governs, as on the set of options available to those who govern (Guzm~ 1991a, 1991b, 1991c). For an analysis of the 1980 Constitution, see Maira (1988). 58. For a detailed discussion of the reforms, see Andrade (1991); Ensalaco (1994); Geisse and Ramffez (1989); and Loveman (1991). 59. See, for example, Boeninger (1979) and PDC (1984). 60. For the Aylwin administration's electoral reform bill, see El Diario, March 18, 1992.

61. See, for example, Hoy, November 7-13, 1995.

62. As one government official put it, "it has saved us" (author interview with Ignacio Walker, chief of political and institutional relations, Ministerio Secretaria de la Presidencia, Santiago, March 9, 1993). 63. See Hoy, November 25-December 1, 1991. Frei went so far as to declare publicly that he would exercise each and every one of the generous faculties that the Constitution had bestowed on him and that eventual reforms aimed at reducing those faculties would apply to his succes- sors (APSI, March 21-April 3, 1994). The CPPD's parliamentarians, meanwhile, were far less enamored of the extensive powers that the Constitution had given the Executive (Hoy, July 15- 30 Studies in Comparative International Development / Fall 1999 21 and November 25-December 1, 1991). They were more inclined to replace the presidential system with a parliamentary or semi-presidential one (C~nara de Diputados 1992). 64. For a discussion of the role of the Secretary General of the Presidency, see Rehren (1993).

65. For the CPPD's anti-populist conception of "governance," see Boeninger (1992).

66. For the Aylwin administration's constitutional reform bill, see El Diario, March 19, 1992 and El Mercurio, June 2, 1992. 67.

Hoy, April 15-21, 1996.

68.

Hoy, March 28-April 3 and April 18-24, 1994; Qud Pasa, August 27, 1994; APS1, April 4-17, 1994. For a description of the various constitutional reform proposals advanced by the Frei administration, see Hoy, March 4-10, 1996. 69. As described in section III, despite its comparatively greater capacity in the area of macroeco- nomic policy, the government was unable to prevent a steady appreciation of the peso during 1990-1997. With the onset of the East Asian crisis, however, the opposite problem has oc- curred, with the government forced to defend the value of the peso, by among other things abandoning controls on the entry of short-term capital. 70. A dramatic example of the limitations on the state's capacity was the Constitutional Tribunal's February 1995 ruling that severely restricted the Central Bank's legal powers to regulate pri- vate banks indebted to it as a result of the 1983 financial crisis. See Hoy, February 13-19, 1995. 71. Author interviews with business leaders, October 1992-July 1993. For more on business' pos- ture toward the Constitution, see Barrett (1998a); C~lceres (1992); and CPC (1993). 72. The state's diminishing power vis-a-vis business contrasts with the Pinochet regime, whose distinguishing feature was its capacity to discipline business in carrying out a radical reorien- tation of Chile's development model. This was, to be sure, discipline of a limited sort, for it did not go much beyond enforcing market discipline and in fact gave rise to unchecked financial speculation that led to the economic crisis of the early 1980s. Moreover, while during the latter half of the 1980s, the regime implemented a series of policies that more effectively channeled investment into productive activities, the state's capacity to discipline business remained far short of that witnessed in East Asia. Nevertheless, the radical reorientation of the economy during the 1970s demonstrated a greater capacity to discipline business than that of any of Pinochet's civilian predecessors or military neighbors. And while business pressed for many of the policy changes the regime adopted in the latter half of the 1980s, economic policy re- mained very much an initiative of the state. More importantly perhaps, the growing power of capital proved to be an asset of the Pinochet regime in its efforts to preserve and project its transformative project beyond military rule. It may well have been that had Pinochet won the plebiscite and remained in office, the state's power vis-h-vis capital would have diminished tremendously. But that problem was left to Pinochet's civilian successors, who in addition to a highly distrustful and increasingly powerful business class, confronted a set of institutional constraints the military regime did not. The military regime also presided in the 1980s over a stage in Chile's export-led development that did not require the same kind of disciplinary capacity that a more advanced stage is likely to require. For a discussion of state-business relations under military rule, see Barrett 1998a. 73. Appointments at the undersecretary level, however, sought to achieve a political balance by naming individuals with different party affiliations than the Ministers they served (Hoy, Febru- ary 26-March 4, 1996). 74.

Hoy, April 3-9, May 1-7, and May 8-14, 1995; Qu~ Pasa, March 15, 1997, APSI, September 6-19, 1993. 75. The evolution of the party system is examined in greater detail in Barrett (forthcoming).

76. For an analysis of the role of the structure of state decision-making in the emergence, crisis, and collapse of Chile's previous compromise, see Barrett (1997), chapters Three and Four. References AGACINO, RAFAEL 1995 'Todo 1o flexible se desvanece': el caso Chileno. In Flexibilidad y condiciones de trabajo precarias, edited by Rafael Agacino and Magdalena Echeverr~a. Santiago: PET Barrett 31 1996 Cinco ecuaciones 'virtuosas' del modelo econ6mico chileno y orientaciones para una nueva polftica econ6mica. In Economia y Trabajo en Chile, Informe Annual, I995-1996 (PET) AGACINO, RAFAEL, GONZALO RIVAS, AND ENRIQUE ROMAN 1992 Apertura y eficiencia productiva: la experiencia chilena 1975- 1989, Documento de Trabajo, no.92, Programa de Econom/a del Trabajo. AGOS1N, MANUEL 1995 E1 retorno de los capitales ex~'anjeros privados a Chile. El Trimestre Econ6mico, LXII (4), October-December, no. 248. AGOSIN, MANUEL AND RICARDO FFRENCH-DAVIS 1995 Managing capital inflows in Latin America. United Nations Development Program, Office of Development Studies, Discussion Paper Series, no. 8 (New York). ALBUQUERQUE, MARIO 1997 E1 sistema privado de pensiones: caso chileno. In La seguridad social en America Latina: greforma o liquidaci6n?, edited by Jaime Ensignia and Rolando Diaz. Caracas: Editorial Nueva Sociedad). AMSDEN, ALICE 1989 Asia's next giant: South Korea and late industrialization. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

1992 A theory of government intervention in late industrialization, in Putterman and Rueschemeyer, eds. ANDRADE, CARLOS 1991 Reforma de la constitucidn politica de la Rep(tblica de Chile de 1980. Santiago: Editorial Jur/dica de Chile. ANINAT, EDUARDO AND CHRISTIAN LARRAIN 1996 Capital Flows: Lessons from the Chilean Experience. CEPAL Review, 60 (December):39-48.

ARELLANO, JOSE PABLO 1984 Politicas sociales y desarrollo: Chile 1924-1984. Santiago: CIEPLAN. BARRETT, PATRICK 1997 Forging compromise: Business, parties, and regime change in Chile. Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation, Department of Political Science, University of Wisconsin-Madison. 1998a Business, regime change, and socio-political compromise in Chile, 1983-1997. Global Studies Program, Working Papers Series, University of Wisconsin-Madison. 1998b Business-labor relations in the new Chilean democracy. Paper presented at the XXI Inter- national Congress of the Latin American Studies Association, Chicago, IL, September 24-26. 1999 Regime change and the transformation of state-capital relations in Chile, ms.

Forth- Regime change, democratic stability, and the transformation of the Chilean party system.

coming Journal of lnteramerican Studies and Worm Affairs.

BARRETr, PATRICK AND VIVEK CHIBBER 1998 Disciplining capital: Industrial policy in post-war Chile, India, and South Korea. Paper presented to the XXI International Congress of the Latin American Studies Association, Chicago, 1L, September 24-26. BARRIENTOS, ARMANDO t 992 Pension reform and economic development in Chile. Development Policy Review, 11:91-107.

BLOCK, FRED 1987 Revising state theory. Philadelphia: Temple University Press).

BOIX, CARLES 1998 Political parties, growth, and equality: Conservative and social democratic economic strat- egies in the worm economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press). BOEN1NGER, EDGARDO 1979 Constituci6n y orden econ6mico. Mensaje, no.281 (August):462~58.

1992 Governance and development: Issues and constraints. Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics. CACERES, CARLOS 1992 /,Ha sido autoritario el gobierno de Aylwin? Libertad y Desarrollo, II: 12, July.

CAMARA DE D1PUTADOS 1992 Informe de la comisi6n especial de estudio del r6gimen polftico Chileno. Revista de Ciencia Politica, XIV (1-2): 149-180. 32 Studies in Comparative International Development / Fall 1999 CENTRAL BANK OF CHILE Various Numbers Boletfn Mensual CERNY, PHILIP 1991 The Limits of deregulation: Transnational interpenetration and policy change.

European Journal of Political Research, 19:173-196. 1993 ed., Finance and world politics: Markets, regimes, and states in the post-hegemonic era. Aldershot, UK: Edward Elgar. CHANG, HA-JOON AND BOB ROWTHORN, EDS.

1995 The role of the state in economic change.

Oxford: Clarendon Press.

CHU, YU-HAN 1995 The East Asian NICs: A state-led path to the developed world. In Global change, regional response: The new internationalcontext of development, edited by Barbara Stallings. Cam- bridge: Cambridge University Press. CLAUDE, MARCEL 1997 Una vez rods la miseria: gEs Chile un pals sustentable?

Santiago: LOM Ediciones.

VITTORIO AND STANLEY FISCHER 1993 Lessons from the Chilean stabilization and recovery. In The Chilean economy: Policy les- sons and challenges, edited by Barry Bosworth, Rudiger Dornbusch, and Radl Lab~in.

Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution. CORTAZAR, RENE 1993 Polftica laboral en el Chile democr~itico: avances y deaffos en los noventa. Santiago: CIEPLAN: Domen. 1996 A labor policy for a new reality. In Social and economic policies in Chile's transition to democracy Criststomo Pizarro, Dagmar Raczynski, and Joaqufn Vial. Santiago: CIEPLAN CPC (CONFEDERACION DE LA PRODUCCION Y DEL COMERCIO) 1993 Confederacitn de la produccitn y del comercio en torno a proyectos de reformas constitucionales, mimeo (August 17). CPPD (CONCERTACION DE PARTIDOS POR LA DEMOCRACIA) 1989 Programa de gobierno.

DEYO, FREDERIC 1987 Coalitions, institutions, and linkage sequencing--Toward a strategic, capacity model of East Asian development. In The political economy of the New East Asian industrialism.

Ithaca: Comell University Press. DIAMOND, PETER AND SALVADOR VALDES-PRIETO 1994 Social security reforms, in Barry Bosworth, et al.

DIAZ, ALVARO 1995 Chile: la industria en la segunda fase exportadora: trayectoria hist6rica y desaffos para los noventa. In Estabilizacidn macroeconomica, reforma estructural y comportamiento in- dustrial: Estructura y funcionamiento del sector manufacturero latinoamericano en los ahos noventa, edited by Jorge Katz. Santiago: CEPAL/IDRC/Alianza Editorial. 1996 Chile: Neoliberal policy, socioeconomic reorganization, and urban labor market. In Glo- bal restructuring, employment, and social inequality in urban Latin America, edited by Richard Tardanicoand Rafael Menjfvar Larfn. Miami: North-South Center Press. DOREMUS, PAUL, WILLIAM KELLER, LOUIS PAULY, AND SIMON REICH 1998 The myth of the global corporation.

Princeton: Princeton University Press.

ECLAC (ECONOMIC COMMISSION FOR LATIN AMERICA) 1997 Preliminary overview of the economy of Latin America and the Caribbean.

Santiago: United Nations. ENSALACO, MARK 1994 In with the new, out with the old? The democratizing impact of constitutional reform in Chile.

Journal of Latin American Studies, 26:409--429. EPSTEIN, GERALD AND JULIET SCHOR 1990 Macropolicy in the rise and fall of the golden age. In The golden age of capitalism: Rein- terpreting the post-war experience, edited by Stephen Marglin and Juliet Schor. Oxford:

Oxford University Press. Barrett 33 ESPING-ANDERSEN, GOSTA 1990 The three worlds of welfare capitalism. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

FAJNZYLBER, FERNANDO 1991 Unavoidable industrial restructuring in Latin America. Durham: Duke University Press.

FAZIO, HUGO 1997 Mapa actual de la extrema riqueza en Chile. Santiago: LOM-ARCIS.

FFRENCH-DAVIS, RICARDO AND RAUL LABAN 1996 Macroeconomic performance and achievements in Chile. In Cris6stomo Pizarro, et al., eds.

FFRENCH-DAVIS, RICARDO, MANUEL AGOS1N, AND ANDRAS UTHOFF 1995 Capital movements, export strategy, and macroeconomic stability in Chile. In Coping with capital surges: The Return of finance to Latin America, edited by Ricardo Ffrench-Davis and Stephanie Griffith Jones. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner. FISHLOW, ALBERT 1990 The Latin American state. Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol.4, no.3 (summer):61-74.

FRIAS, PATRICIO 1992 La afiliacion sindical en Chile: 1932-1992. Economfa y Trabajo, I (2):263-89.

1994 Sindicatos en la transici6n: en la bdsqueda de una nueva identidad. Economia y Trabajo en Chile, Informe Anual, 1993-1994. Santiago: PET. 1995 Sindicalismo y desarrollo de acci6n contestataria. Economia y Trabajo en Chile, Informe Anual, 1994-1995. Santiago: PET. 1996 Desarrollo del sindicalismo chileno, 1995-1996. Economia y Trabajo en Chile, Informe Anual, 1995-1996. Santiago: PET. FRIEDEN, JEFFRY 1991 Invested interests: The politics of national economic policies in a world of global finance. International Organization, vol.45, no.4(Autumn):425-51. GEISSE, FRANCISCO AND JOSE ANTONIO RAMIREZ 1989 La reforma constitucional. Santiago: Ediciones Chile-Am6rica CESOC.

GILLION, COLIN AND ALEJANDRO BONILLA 1992 Analysis of a national private pension scheme: The case of Chile. International Labour Review, 131, 2. GOODMAN, JOHN AND LOUIS PAULY 1993 The obsolescence of capital controls? Economic management in an age of global markets. Worm Politics, vol.46, no.l (October):51-82. GUZMAN, JAIME 1991a Aspectos fundamentales del anteproyecto de constituci6n polftica. Estudios Politicos, no. 42 (Autumn):342-369. 1991b E1 camino politico. Estudios P~blicos, no. 42 (Autumn):369-383. 1991c La definici6n constitucional. Estudios P~blicos, no. 42 (Autumn):383- 417.

HAGGARD, STEPHAN 1990 Pathways from the periphery: The politics of growth in the new industrializing Countries. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. HAINDL, ERIK 1997 Chilean pension fund reform and its impact on savings. In Generating savings for Latin American development, edited by Robert Grosse. Miami: North-South Center Press. HARDY, CLARISA 1997 La reforma social pendiente. Santiago: Fundaci6n Chile 21. HIKK1NO, TAKASHI AND ALICE AMSDEN 1994 Staying behind, stumbling back, sneaking up, soaring ahead: Late industrialization in histori- cal perspective. In Convergence of productivity:Cross national studies of historical evidence, edited by Wdliam Baumol, Richard Nelson, and Edward Wolff. Oxford: Oxford University Press. IMF (INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND) 1997 International fnancial statistics yearbook. Washington, D.C.: IMF. JESSOP, BOB 1990 State theory: Putting capitalist states in their place. University Park: Pennsylvania State University Press. 34 Studies in Comparative International Development / Fall 1999 KOZUL-WRIGHT, RICHARD AND BOB ROWTHORN, EDS.

1995 Transnational corporations and the global economy. New York: St. Martin's Press.

LABAN, RAUL AND FELIPE LARRAIN 1996 The Chilean experience with capital mobility. In The Chilean economy: Policy lessons and challenges, edited by Barry Bosworth, Rudiger Dornbusch, and Ratil Lab~in. Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution. LALL, SANJAYA 1995 Industrial strategy and policies on foreign direct investment in East Asia. Transnational Corporations, vol.4, no.3 (December):l-26. LANDESMANN, MICHAEL 1992 Industrial policies and social corporatism. In Social corporatism: A superior economic system? edited by Jukka Pekkarinen, Matti Pohjola, and Bob Rowthom. Oxford: Clarendon Press. LANDESMANN, MICHAEL AND JUHANA VARTIAINEN t992 Social corporatism and long-term economic performance. In Pekkarinen, et al.

LAVANDERO, JORGE 1996 El dilema de Chile: gCrecimiento sin equidad? Santiago: LOM Ediciones.

LINDBLOM, CHARLES 1977 Politics and markets. New York: Basic Books. LOVEMAN, BRIAN 1991 gMisi6n cumplida? Civil military relations and the Chilean political transition. Journal of lnteramerican Studies and Worm Affairs, vol.33, no.3 (Fall). MAIRA, LUIS 1988 La constituci6n de 1980 y la ruptura democrdtica. Santiago: Editorial Emisi6n.

MARCEL, MARIO AND ALBERTO ARENAS 1992 Social security reform in Chile. IDB Occasional Paper, no.5.

MARQUEZ BELLONI, FRANCISCA 1994 La inserci6n precaria en el trabajo. Proposiciones, no. 25 (October):132-143.

MAYORGA, ROBERTO AND LUIS MONTT 1995 Foreign investment in Chile. Dordrecht/Boston/London: Martinus Nijhoff Publishers.

MACINTYRE, ANDREW, ED.

1994 Business and government in industrializing Asia. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. MELLER, PATRICIO, AND RAUL SAEZ 1995 Lecciones y desafios futuros del auge exportador chileno. In Auge exportador chileno: lecciones y desafios, edited by Patricio Meller and Ratll S~iez. Santiago: C1EPLAN/Dolmen. MESA-LAGO, CARMELO 1989 Ascent to bankruptcy: Financing social security in Latin America Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh. MIDEPLAN (MINISTERIO DE PLANIFICACION Y COOPERACION) 1996 Balance de seis anos de las politicas sociales, 1990-1996. Santiago: MIDEPLAN. MUNOZ, OSCAR 1996 Los proyectos de fomento productivo. In Estado, empresarios, instituciones: estrategias para la transformaci6n productiva, edited Oscar Munoz. Santiago: CEPAL/CIEPLAN. OECD (ORGANIZATION OF ECONOMIC COOPERATION AND DEVELOPMENT) 1997 OECD reviews of foreign direct investment: Chile. Paris: OECD. OKIMOTO, DANIEL 1989 Between MITI and the market: Japanese industrial policy for high technology. Stanford: Stanford University Press. PACK, HOWARD 1992 Learning and productivity change in developing countries. In Trade policy, industrializa- tion, and development, edited by Gerald K. Helleiner. Oxford: Clarendon Press. PACK, HOWARD AND LARRY WESTPHAL 1986 Industrial strategy and technological change: Theory versus reality. Journal of Develop- ment Economics, 22 (1):87-128. PDC (PART/DO DEMOCRATA CRISTIANO) 1984 Proyecto alternativo, three volumes. Santiago: Editorial Aconcagua. Barrett 35 PET (PROGRAMA DE ECONOMIA DEL TRABAJO) 1996 Economla y trabajo en Chile, Informe Annual, 1995-1996. Santiago: PET. PONTUSSON, JONAS 1991 Labor, corporatism, and industrial policy: The Swedish case in comparative perspective. Comparative Politics, 23 (2). 1992 The limits of social democracy: Investment politics in Sweden. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. PUTFERMAN, LOUIS AND DIETRICH RUESCHEMEYER, EDS.

1992 State and market in development: Synergy or rivalry? Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.

QUIROGA, RAYEN AND SAAR VAN HAUWERMEIREN 1996 The tiger without a jungle: Environmental consequences of the economic transformation in Chile. Santiago: Institute of Political Ecology. RACZYNSK1, DAGMAR 1995 Politicas sociales y programas de combate a la pobreza en Chile: balance y desaffos. Colecci6n Estudios CIEPLAN, No.39 (June):9-73. RAMOS, JOSEPH 1993 La institucionalidad laboral:/,Ra'gidez o bien social? mimeo. REHREN, ALFREDO 1993 La presidencia en el gobierno de la Concertaci6n. Estudios Sociales, no. 75:15-38. ROMAN, ENRIQUE AND JOSE ANTONIO ROJAS 1994 E1 acceso de las pequefias y medianas empresas al financiamiento y el programa nacional de apoyo a la PYME del gobierno chileno: Balance preliminar de una experiencia. Santiago: CEPAL. RUIZ-TAGLE, JAIME 1994 La evoluci6n del nuevo sistema de pensiones en Chile. in Economfa y Trabajo en Chile, Informe Anual, 1993-1994. Santiago: PET. 1996 Desarrollo social y politicas ptiblicas en Chile, 1985-1995. In Economia y Trabajo en Chile, Informe Anual, 1995-t996. Santiago: PET. 1997 El nuevo sistema de pensiones ea Chile: una evaluaci6n provisoria (1981-1995). In La segurMad social en America: Latina: i reforma o liquidaci6n? edited by Jaime Ensignia and Rolando Dfaz Caracas Editorial Nueva Sociedad. SAEZ, RAUL, AND R1CARDO FFRENCH-DAVIS 1996 Trade and industrial development in Chile. In Trade and industrialization policies in Mexico and Chile, edited by Montague Lord. Interamerican Development Bank, Working Paper Series, no. 208 (Washington, D.C.). SAPAG, REINALDO 1993 Tareas pendientes con el mundo del trabajo. Santiago: Ediciones Copygraph. SCHARPF, FRITZ 1990 Crisis and choice in European social democracy. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

SCHURMAN, RACHEL 1996 Snails, southern hake, and sustainability: Neoliberalism and natural resource exports in Chile. World Development, vol.24, no. 11, pp. 1695-1709. SCO'IT, CRISTOPHER 1995 The distributive impact of the new economic model in Chile, Development Economics Research Programme, no. 68, London School of Economics and Political Science. SHAPIRO, HELEN AND LANCE TAYLOR 1990 The state and industrial change. World Development, 18(6):861-878. STEWART, MICHAEL 1984 The age of interdependence: Economic policy in a shrinking world. Cambridge and Lon- don: MIT Press. STRANGE, SUSAN 1996 The retreat of the state: The diffusion of power in the world economy. Cambridge: Cam- bridge University Press. UNDERHILL, GEOFFREY 1991 Markets beyond politics? The state and the internationalisation of finance. European Jour- nal of Political Research, 19 (March). 36 Studies in Comparative International Development / Fall 1999 UUSITALO, PAAVO 1984 Monetarism, keynesianism and the institutional status of central banks. Acta Sociologica, 27 (1):31-50. VELASCO, ANDRES 1994 The state and economic policy: Chile 1952-1992. In Bosworth, et al. VERGARA, PILAR 1993 Ruptura y continuidad en la polftica social del gobiemo democr~tico. Estudios Sociales, No.78:105--44. 1994 Las polfticas sociales en Chile. Revista Mexicana de Sociologfa, LVI:3 (July-Septem- ber):205-230. VIAL, JOAQUIN 1996 Policies of economic growth and political transition in Chile. In Social and economic policies in Chile's transition to democracy, edited by Cris6stomo Pizarro, Dagmar Raczynski, and Joaqufn Vial. Santiago: CIEPLAN. WADE, ROBERT 1990 Governing the market: Economic theory and the role of government in East Asian indus- trialization. Princeton: Princeton University Press. 1996 Globalization and its limits: Reports of the death of the national economy are greatly exaggerated. In National diversity and globalcapitalism, edited by Suzanne Berger and Ronald Dore. Ithaca: Comell University Press. WORLD BANK 1995 World development report 1995: Workers in an integrating world Oxford: Oxford Univer- sity Press. 1997a World development report 1997: The state in a changing world Oxford: Oxford University Press. 1997b Chile: poverty and income distribution in a high-growth economy: 1987-1995, two vol- umes, World Bank Report No. 16377-CH. ZYSMAN, JOHN 1983 Governments, markets, and growth: Financial systems and the politics of industrial change. Ithaca: Comell University Press.